![]() |
Economics - Fuqua Fuqua School of Business Duke University |
|
HOME > Fuqua > Economics - Fuqua | Search Help Login |
| Economics - Fuqua : Publications since January 2024List all publications in the database. :chronological alphabetical combined listing:%% Coleman, Wilbur J. @article{fds379329, Author = {Coleman, WJ}, Title = {Corruption and supply-side economics}, Journal = {Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control}, Volume = {168}, Year = {2024}, Month = {November}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2024.104942}, Abstract = {This paper develops a model of the effects of tax rates chosen optimally to promote growth and public welfare in the face of corruption. For a given level of corruption, public spending can promote growth but high tax rates in pursuit of various social goals have potentially significant supply-side economics effects that reduce income. Governments faced with rampant corruption optimally choose low tax rates, thus associating poor countries with low tax rates, and confounding the observed relation between tax rates and income. The model is estimated using cross-country data on income, tax rates, and corruption and is shown to match key features of the data. The chief contribution of this paper is to stress the importance of jointly considering the effects of corruption and taxation in documenting evidence in support of supply-side economics.}, Doi = {10.1016/j.jedc.2024.104942}, Key = {fds379329} } %% Marx, Leslie M. @article{fds376300, Author = {Iossa, E and Loertscher, S and Marx, LM and Rey, P}, Title = {Coordination in the Fight against Collusion}, Journal = {American Economic Journal Microeconomics}, Volume = {16}, Number = {1}, Pages = {224-261}, Year = {2024}, Month = {January}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/mic.20220194}, Abstract = {While antitrust authorities strive to detect, prosecute, and thereby deter collusive conduct, entities harmed by that conduct are also advised to pursue their own strategies to deter collusion. The implications of such delegation of deterrence have largely been ignored, however. In a procurement context, we find that buyers may prefer to accommodate rather than deter collusion among their suppliers. We also show that a multimarket buyer, such as a centralized procurement authority, may optimally deter collusion when multiple independent buyers would not, consistent with the view that “large” buyers are less susceptible to collusion.}, Doi = {10.1257/mic.20220194}, Key = {fds376300} } %% McAdams, David @book{fds383467, Author = {Dixit, AK and Skeath, S and McAdams, D}, Title = {Games of Strategy}, Year = {2025}, Month = {June}, ISBN = {9781324087137}, Abstract = {Invites all students to understand game theory}, Key = {fds383467} } @article{fds383584, Author = {Fawole, A and Boyer, B and Shahid, M and Bharali, I and McAdams, D and Yamey, G}, Title = {What are the key features of an equitable global vaccine strategy for the next pandemic? A qualitative study of pandemic control experts.}, Journal = {Vaccine}, Volume = {61}, Pages = {127377}, Year = {2025}, Month = {June}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.vaccine.2025.127377}, Abstract = {<h4>Background</h4>The COVID-19 pandemic exposed significant weaknesses in global health multilateralism, particularly in its failure to achieve fair and equitable global distribution of COVID-19 vaccines. Soon after vaccines were available, huge inequities in vaccination rates between populations in the global north and the global south became apparent. This study explores why multilateralism fell so short during the pandemic and identifies the steps that must be taken now to ensure global vaccine equity in the next pandemic.<h4>Methods</h4>We conducted in-depth interviews with 20 expert key informants (KIs) worldwide from May 2023 to January 2024, comprising 16 individual interviews and two group interviews (each group interview had two KIs). The experts included representatives of academia, multilateral health and development agencies, civil society organizations, non-governmental organizations, think tanks, and the pharmaceutical industry. We used a qualitative study design to explore the perspectives, experiences, and insights of global health experts. We used purposive sampling to select participants based on their experience and knowledge of pandemic vaccines and pandemic preparedness. We continued conducting interviews until we had reached theoretical saturation.<h4>Findings</h4>Five key themes emerged on why multilateralism fell short when it came to global COVID-19 vaccine distribution. Prioritization of national interests-so-called "vaccine nationalism"-was a barrier to sharing doses. COVAX, the global vaccine sharing mechanism, lacked incentives for high-income and upper-middle-income nations to participate or compulsory mechanisms to make them do so, undercutting its ability to serve as an equitable distribution platform. COVAX also left out important constituents from the decision-making process. Rich countries benefitted from having stronger market power in the global economy due to their established, long-term relationships with the pharmaceutical companies. Inadequate vaccine supply fed into inequitable distribution. Five key themes emerged on ways to avert global vaccine inequity in the next pandemic. Promoting regional self-sufficiency in research and development and vaccine manufacturing is crucial. Building manufacturing capacity cannot be deferred until the next pandemic-it must begin now. International collective action will still be important, especially technology transfer agreements between large companies in the global north and partners in the global south as well as south-south partnerships. Public funding for pandemic vaccine development should include conditionalities that support global access. Finally, new kinds of intellectual property agreements are essential in preparing for the next pandemic.<h4>Interpretation</h4>Vaccine nationalism-combined with vaccine supply constraints, the dominance of manufacturing by countries in the global north, and the greater purchasing power of wealthy nations-created a "perfect storm" for rich nations to buy up the supply and to leave COVAX and many low- and middle-income countries at the back of the queue. To prevent such inequity in the next pandemic, regions should build capacity not just in manufacturing vaccines but also in regulatory approval and the financing and procurement of vaccines at scale. Such capacity needs to be built now-it cannot be deferred until the next crisis.<h4>Funding</h4>This study was funded by a research grant to Duke University from the Carnegie Corporation of New York (https://www.carnegie.org/grants/grants-database/?q=duke&per_page=25#!/grants/grants-database/grant/937399121.0/).}, Doi = {10.1016/j.vaccine.2025.127377}, Key = {fds383584} } @article{fds383469, Author = {McAdams, D and Song, Y}, Title = {Adoption epidemics and viral marketing}, Journal = {Theoretical Economics}, Volume = {20}, Number = {2}, Pages = {453-480}, Publisher = {The Econometric Society}, Year = {2025}, Month = {May}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.3982/TE5886}, Abstract = {An innovation (e.g., new product or idea) spreads like a virus, transmitted by those who have previously adopted it. Agents update their beliefs about innovation quality based on private signals and when they hear about the innovation. We characterize equilibrium adoption dynamics and the resulting lifecycle of virally-spread innovations. Herding on adoption can occur but only early in the innovation lifecycle, and adoption eventually ceases for all virally-spread innovations. A producer capable of advertising directly to consumers finds it optimal to wait and allow awareness to grow virally initially after launch.}, Doi = {10.3982/TE5886}, Key = {fds383469} } @article{fds379307, Author = {McAdams, D and Day, T}, Title = {The political economy of epidemic management}, Journal = {Review of Economic Design}, Volume = {29}, Number = {1}, Pages = {115-148}, Year = {2025}, Month = {February}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10058-024-00357-x}, Abstract = {During an infectious-disease epidemic, a political leader imposes “stay-at-home orders” (limiting activity) or “go-out orders” (mandating activity) whenever preferred by the majority of the citizenry over the no-intervention status quo. We characterize the resulting equilibrium epidemic trajectory in an economic-epidemiological model that allows for asymptomatic infection and social-economic complementarities of activity, assuming that citizens are myopic optimizers. We find that the qualitative features of equilibrium policy dynamics hinge critically on whether the pathogen is transmitted before or after infected people have developed symptoms. If transmission only occurs symptomatically, then the leader never imposes stay-at-home orders on the healthy but may impose go-out orders during some phases of the epidemic. However, if transmission occurs asymptomatically, the leader never imposes go-out orders on the healthy.}, Doi = {10.1007/s10058-024-00357-x}, Key = {fds379307} } @article{fds383010, Author = {Avery, CN and McAdams, D}, Title = {The economics of epidemics: introduction to the special issue, part two}, Journal = {Review of Economic Design}, Volume = {29}, Number = {1}, Pages = {1-7}, Year = {2025}, Month = {February}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10058-025-00378-0}, Doi = {10.1007/s10058-025-00378-0}, Key = {fds383010} } @article{fds381075, Author = {Avery, CN and McAdams, D}, Title = {The economics of epidemics: introduction to the special issue: The economics of epidemics: introduction to the special issue: C. N. Avery, D. Mcadams}, Journal = {Review of Economic Design}, Volume = {28}, Number = {4}, Pages = {631-637}, Year = {2024}, Month = {December}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10058-024-00370-0}, Doi = {10.1007/s10058-024-00370-0}, Key = {fds381075} } @article{fds383468, Author = {Avery, C and Chen, F and McAdams, D}, Title = {Steady-State Social Distancing and Vaccination}, Journal = {American Economic Review: Insights}, Volume = {6}, Number = {1}, Pages = {1-19}, Publisher = {American Economic Association}, Year = {2024}, Month = {March}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aeri.20220699}, Abstract = {<jats:p> This paper analyzes an economic-epidemiological model of infectious disease where it is possible to become infected more than once and individual agents make endogenous choices of social distancing and vaccine adoption. Protective actions adopted by any one person reduce future risks to other people. The positive externalities associated with these behaviors provide motivation for vaccine and social-distancing subsidies, but subsidizing one protective action reduces incentives for other protective actions. A vaccine subsidy increases vaccine adoption and reduces steady-state infection prevalence; a social distancing subsidy can either increase or reduce steady-state infection prevalence. (JEL D62, D91, I12, I18) </jats:p>}, Doi = {10.1257/aeri.20220699}, Key = {fds383468} } | |
Duke University * Economics - Fuqua * Faculty * Affiliated * Staff * Reload * Login |