Economics Faculty Database
Economics
Arts & Sciences
Duke University

 HOME > Arts & Sciences > Economics > Faculty    Search Help Login pdf version printable version 

Publications of Christopher D. Timmins    :chronological  alphabetical  combined listing:

%% Journal Articles   
@article{fds370033,
   Author = {Gao, X and Song, R and Timmins, C},
   Title = {Information, migration, and the value of clean
             air},
   Journal = {Journal of Development Economics},
   Volume = {163},
   Year = {2023},
   Month = {June},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2023.103079},
   Abstract = {Using a variant of the Rosen-Roback model of inter-city
             migration that incorporates public access to air quality
             information, we demonstrate that information constraints
             create a wedge between revealed and true hedonic prices for
             pollution that depends upon individuals’ perception
             biases. We empirically test our theoretical predictions by
             leveraging the unexpected disclosure of PM2.5 data in China.
             We find that migration decisions become much more responsive
             to pollution and that the hedonic price of avoiding PM2.5
             exposure nearly doubles – from 171 to 336 Chinese Yuan –
             in response to the information shock. Our results highlight
             the role of imperfect information in migration decisions and
             its impact on non-market valuation in countries where public
             access to information is restricted.},
   Doi = {10.1016/j.jdeveco.2023.103079},
   Key = {fds370033}
}

@article{fds364042,
   Author = {Christensen, P and Timmins, C},
   Title = {Sorting or Steering: The Effects of Housing Discrimination
             on Neighborhood Choice},
   Journal = {Journal of Political Economy},
   Volume = {130},
   Number = {8},
   Pages = {2110-2163},
   Year = {2022},
   Month = {August},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/720140},
   Abstract = {Growing evidence indicates that neighborhoods affect human
             capital accumulation, raising concern that the exclusionary
             effects of housing discrimination could contribute to
             persistent inequality in the United States. Using data from
             HUD’s most recent Housing Discrimination Study and
             microlevel data on neighborhood attributes in 28 US cities,
             we find that minorities are steered toward neighborhoods
             with less economic opportunity and greater exposures to
             crime and pollution. Holding preferences and income
             constant, discriminatory steering alone can explain a
             disproportionate number of minority households found in
             high-poverty neighborhoods in the United States and the
             higher exposure of African American mothers to toxic
             pollutants.},
   Doi = {10.1086/720140},
   Key = {fds364042}
}

@article{fds363882,
   Author = {Timmins, C and Vissing, A},
   Title = {Environmental justice and Coasian bargaining: The role of
             race, ethnicity, and income in lease negotiations for shale
             gas},
   Journal = {Journal of Environmental Economics and Management},
   Volume = {114},
   Year = {2022},
   Month = {July},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2022.102657},
   Abstract = {Using a unique combination of datasets and estimation
             techniques, we test whether private lease negotiations to
             extract oil and natural gas exhibit features of Coasian
             efficiency. We demonstrate that measures of wealth
             (including income, house square footage, and land acreage),
             typically determinants of willingness to pay for
             environmental quality, do affect bargaining outcomes.
             However, race, ethnicity, and language also play important
             roles after conditioning upon these variables, suggesting an
             environmental injustice and a breakdown of efficient Coasian
             bargaining. We further demonstrate that failure to negotiate
             protections in leases leads to increased risk of future
             drilling violations, and that weak lease restrictions are
             not generally offset by strong local ordinance
             restrictions.},
   Doi = {10.1016/j.jeem.2022.102657},
   Key = {fds363882}
}

@article{fds364273,
   Author = {Christensen, P and Sarmiento-Barbieri, I and Timmins,
             C},
   Title = {HOUSING DISCRIMINATION AND THE TOXICS EXPOSURE GAP IN THE
             UNITED STATES: EVIDENCE FROM THE RENTAL MARKET},
   Journal = {The Review of Economics and Statistics},
   Volume = {104},
   Number = {4},
   Pages = {807-818},
   Year = {2022},
   Month = {July},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1162/rest_a_00992},
   Abstract = {Local pollution exposures have a disproportionate impact on
             minority households, but the root causes remain unclear.
             This study conducts a correspondence experiment on a major
             online housing platform to test whether housing
             discrimination constrains minority access to housing options
             in markets with significant sources of airborne chemical
             toxics. We find that renters with African American or
             Hispanic/Latinx names are 41% less likely than renters with
             white names to receive responses for properties in
             low-exposure locations. We find no evidence of
             discriminatory constraints in high-exposure locations,
             indicating that discrimination increases relative access to
             housing choices at elevated exposure risk.},
   Doi = {10.1162/rest_a_00992},
   Key = {fds364273}
}

@article{fds361797,
   Author = {Monsour, M and Clarke-Rubright, E and Lieberman-Cribbin, W and Timmins, C and Taioli, E and Schwartz, RM and Corley, SS and Laucis, AM and Morey, RA},
   Title = {The impact of climate change on the prevalence of mental
             illness symptoms.},
   Journal = {J Affect Disord},
   Volume = {300},
   Pages = {430-440},
   Year = {2022},
   Month = {March},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jad.2021.12.124},
   Abstract = {BACKGROUND: The repercussions of climate change threaten the
             population with an increased prevalence of extreme climate
             events. We explored the impact of climate change induced sea
             level rise (SLR) and tropical cyclone (TC) exposure on
             mental illness symptom prevalence. METHODS: Using three
             datasets, TC exposure scores were calculated for each
             subject to determine how exposure affects posttraumatic
             stress disorder (PTSD), anxiety, and major depressive
             disorder (MDD) symptom prevalence. Inundation mapping of
             various SLR and storm surge (SS) scenarios were performed
             for the susceptible region of Miami-Dade and Broward
             counties to determine the population impact of flooding.
             RESULTS: We found an elevated risk of mental illness
             symptoms from exposure to more high- intensity TCs and
             identified demographic variables that may contribute to this
             risk. Furthermore, inundation mapping demonstrated severe
             and widespread impact of SLR and SS on the mental health of
             communities. LIMITATIONS: This study did not include data
             directly measuring comorbidity, resilience, preparedness, or
             ability to adapt to climate change. Also, multiple
             imputation using chained equations may have been imperfect.
             Furthermore, there is uncertainty in predicting and mapping
             SLR and TC intensity, which limits complete confidence in
             our SS predictions. CONCLUSION: The impacts of climate
             change have been frequently studied in terms of physical
             health, natural disaster prevalence, and economic impacts,
             but rarely on mental health burden. However, it is vital
             that national, state, and local governments develop and
             deploy plans to address mental health needs along with
             expenditures for protecting infrastructure, the economy, and
             physical health from the combined effects of SLR and climate
             change-induced natural disasters.},
   Doi = {10.1016/j.jad.2021.12.124},
   Key = {fds361797}
}

@article{fds354994,
   Author = {Gibbons, S and Heblich, S and Timmins, C},
   Title = {Market tremors: Shale gas exploration, earthquakes, and
             their impact on house prices},
   Journal = {Journal of Urban Economics},
   Volume = {122},
   Year = {2021},
   Month = {March},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jue.2020.103313},
   Abstract = {Shale gas has grown to become a major new source of energy
             in countries around the globe. While its importance for
             energy supply is well recognized, there has also been public
             concern over potential risks from hydraulic fracturing
             (‘fracking’). Although commercial development has not
             yet taken place in the UK, licenses for drilling were issued
             in 2008, signalling potential future development. This paper
             examines whether public fears about fracking affect house
             prices in areas that have been licensed for shale gas
             exploration. Our estimates suggest differentiated effects.
             Licensing did not affect house prices but fracking the first
             well in 2011, which caused two minor earthquakes, did. We
             find a 3.9–4.7 percent house price decrease in the area
             where the earthquakes occurred. The earthquakes were too
             minor to have caused any damage but we find the effect on
             prices extends to a radius of about 25 km served by local
             newspapers. This evidence suggests that the earthquakes and
             newspaper coverage increased awareness of exploration
             activity and fear of the local consequences.},
   Doi = {10.1016/j.jue.2020.103313},
   Key = {fds354994}
}

@article{fds360654,
   Author = {Bishop, KC and Kuminoff, NV and Banzhaf, HS and Boyle, KJ and von
             Gravenitz, K and Pope, JC and Smith, VK and Timmins,
             CD},
   Title = {Best practices for using hedonic property value models to
             measure willingness to pay for environmental
             quality},
   Journal = {Review of Environmental Economics and Policy},
   Volume = {14},
   Number = {2},
   Pages = {260-281},
   Year = {2020},
   Month = {July},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/reep/reaa001},
   Doi = {10.1093/reep/reaa001},
   Key = {fds360654}
}

@article{fds346743,
   Author = {Banzhaf, HS and Ma, L and Timmins, C},
   Title = {Environmental Justice: Establishing Causal
             Relationships},
   Journal = {Annual Review of Resource Economics},
   Volume = {11},
   Pages = {377-398},
   Year = {2019},
   Month = {October},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1146/annurev-resource-100518-094131},
   Abstract = {The environmental justice literature has found that the poor
             and people of color are disproportionately exposed to
             pollution. This literature has sparked a broad activist
             movement and several policy reforms in the United States and
             internationally. In this article, we review the literature
             documenting correlations between pollution and demographics
             and the history of the related movement, focusing on the
             United States. We then turn to the potential causal
             mechanisms behind the observed correlations. Given its focus
             on causal econometric models, we argue that economics has a
             comparative advantage in evaluating these mechanisms. We
             consider (a) profit-maximizing decisions by firms, (b)
             Tiebout-like utility-maximizing decisions by households in
             the presence of income disparities, (c) Coasean negotiations
             between both sides, (d) political economy explanations and
             governmental failures, and (e) intergenerational
             transmission of poverty. Proper identification of the causal
             mechanisms underlying observed disproportionate exposures is
             critical to the design of effective policy to remedy
             them.},
   Doi = {10.1146/annurev-resource-100518-094131},
   Key = {fds346743}
}

@article{fds342133,
   Author = {Freeman, R and Liang, W and Song, R and Timmins, C},
   Title = {Willingness to pay for clean air in China},
   Journal = {Journal of Environmental Economics and Management},
   Volume = {94},
   Pages = {188-216},
   Year = {2019},
   Month = {March},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2019.01.005},
   Abstract = {We use a residential sorting model incorporating migration
             disutility to recover the implicit value of clean air in
             China. The model is estimated using China Population Census
             Data along with PM2.5 satellite data. Our study provides new
             evidence on the willingness to pay for air quality
             improvements in developing countries and is the first
             application of an equilibrium sorting model to the valuation
             of non-market amenities in China. We employ two instrumental
             variables based on coal-fired electricity generation and
             wind direction to address the endogeneity of local air
             pollution. Results suggest important differences between the
             residential sorting model and a conventional hedonic model,
             highlighting the role of moving costs and the discreteness
             of the choice set. Our sorting results indicate that the
             economic value of air quality improvement associated with a
             one-unit decline in PM2.5 concentration is up to $8.83
             billion for all Chinese households in 2005.},
   Doi = {10.1016/j.jeem.2019.01.005},
   Key = {fds342133}
}

@article{fds341378,
   Author = {Banzhaf, S and Ma, L and Timmins, C},
   Title = {Environmental Justice: the Economics of Race, Place, and
             Pollution.},
   Journal = {The Journal of Economic Perspectives : a Journal of the
             American Economic Association},
   Volume = {33},
   Number = {1},
   Pages = {185-208},
   Year = {2019},
   Month = {January},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/jep.33.1.185},
   Doi = {10.1257/jep.33.1.185},
   Key = {fds341378}
}

@article{fds340432,
   Author = {Bishop, KC and Timmins, C},
   Title = {Estimating the marginal willingness to pay function without
             instrumental variables},
   Journal = {Journal of Urban Economics},
   Volume = {109},
   Pages = {66-83},
   Publisher = {Elsevier BV},
   Year = {2019},
   Month = {January},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jue.2018.11.006},
   Abstract = {The hedonic model of Rosen (1974) has become a workhorse for
             valuing the characteristics of differentiated products
             despite a number of well-documented econometric problems,
             including a source of endogeneity that has proven difficult
             to overcome. Here we outline a simple, likelihood-based
             estimation approach for recovering the marginal
             willingness-to-pay function that avoids this endogeneity
             problem. Using this framework, we find that marginal
             willingness-to-pay to avoid violent crime increases by
             sixteen cents with each additional incident per 100,000
             residents. Accounting for the slope of the marginal
             willingness-to-pay function has significant impacts on
             welfare analyses.},
   Doi = {10.1016/j.jue.2018.11.006},
   Key = {fds340432}
}

@article{fds335440,
   Author = {Bishop, KC and Timmins, C},
   Title = {Using panel data to easily estimate hedonic demand
             functions},
   Journal = {Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource
             Economists},
   Volume = {5},
   Number = {3},
   Pages = {517-543},
   Publisher = {University of Chicago Press},
   Year = {2018},
   Month = {July},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/696981},
   Abstract = {The hedonics literature has often asserted that if one were
             able to observe the same individual make multiple purchase
             decisions, one could recover rich estimates of preference
             heterogeneity for a given amenity. In particular, in the
             face of a changing price schedule, observing each individual
             twice is sufficient to recover a linear demand function
             separately for each individual, with no additional
             restrictions. Constructing a rich panel data set of buyers,
             we recover the full distribution of demand functions for
             clean air in the Bay Area of California. First, we find that
             estimating the full demand function, rather than simply
             recovering a local estimate of marginal willingness to pay,
             is important. Second, we find evidence of considerable
             heterogeneity, which is important from a policy perspective;
             our data-driven estimates of the welfare effects associated
             with a nonmarginal change in air quality differ
             substantially from those recovered using the existing
             approaches to welfare estimation.},
   Doi = {10.1086/696981},
   Key = {fds335440}
}

@article{fds347631,
   Author = {Haninger, K and Ma, L and Timmins, C},
   Title = {The value of brownfield remediation},
   Journal = {Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource
             Economists},
   Volume = {4},
   Number = {1},
   Pages = {197-241},
   Year = {2017},
   Month = {March},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/689743},
   Abstract = {The US Environmental Protection Agency Brownfields Program
             awards grants to redevelop contaminated lands known as
             brownfields. This paper estimates cleanup benefits by
             combining administrative records for a nationally
             representative sample of brownfields with high-resolution,
             high-frequency housing data. With cleanup, we find that
             property values increase by an average of 5.0% to 11.5%. For
             a welfare interpretation that does not rely on the
             intertemporal stability of the hedonic price function, a
             double-difference matching estimator finds even larger
             effects of up to 15.2%. Our various specifications lead to
             the consistent conclusion that Brownfields Program cleanups
             yield positive, statistically significant, but highly
             localized effects on housing prices.},
   Doi = {10.1086/689743},
   Key = {fds347631}
}

@article{fds316004,
   Author = {Bayer, P and McMillan, R and Murphy, A and Timmins,
             C},
   Title = {A Dynamic Model of Demand for Houses and
             Neighborhoods},
   Journal = {Econometrica},
   Volume = {84},
   Number = {3},
   Pages = {893-942},
   Publisher = {The Econometric Society},
   Year = {2016},
   Month = {May},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.3982/ECTA10170},
   Abstract = {This paper develops a dynamic model of neighborhood choice
             along with a computationally light multi-step estimator. The
             proposed empirical framework captures observed and
             unobserved preference heterogeneity across households and
             locations in a flexible way. We estimate the model using a
             newly assembled data set that matches demographic
             information from mortgage applications to the universe of
             housing transactions in the San Francisco Bay Area from 1994
             to 2004. The results provide the first estimates of the
             marginal willingness to pay for several non-marketed
             amenities-neighborhood air pollution, violent crime, and
             racial composition-in a dynamic framework. Comparing these
             estimates with those from a static version of the model
             highlights several important biases that arise when dynamic
             considerations are ignored.},
   Doi = {10.3982/ECTA10170},
   Key = {fds316004}
}

@article{fds314313,
   Author = {Muehlenbachs, L and Spiller, E and Timmins, C},
   Title = {The housing market impacts of shale gas development:
             Corrigendum},
   Journal = {American Economic Review},
   Volume = {106},
   Number = {2},
   Pages = {475},
   Publisher = {American Economic Association},
   Year = {2016},
   Month = {February},
   ISSN = {0002-8282},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.106.2.475},
   Doi = {10.1257/aer.106.2.475},
   Key = {fds314313}
}

@article{fds314314,
   Author = {Muehlenbachs, L and Spiller, E and Timmins, C},
   Title = {The housing market impacts of shale gas development},
   Journal = {American Economic Review},
   Volume = {105},
   Number = {12},
   Pages = {3633-3659},
   Publisher = {American Economic Association},
   Year = {2015},
   Month = {December},
   ISSN = {0002-8282},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.20140079},
   Abstract = {Using data from Pennsylvania and an array of empirical
             techniques to control for confounding factors, we recover
             hedonic estimates of property value impacts from nearby
             shale gas development that vary with water source, well
             productivity, and visibility. Results indicate large
             negative impacts on nearby groundwater-dependent homes,
             while piped-water-dependent homes exhibit smaller positive
             impacts, suggesting benefits from lease payments. Results
             have implications for the debate over regulation of shale
             gas development.},
   Doi = {10.1257/aer.20140079},
   Key = {fds314314}
}

@article{fds239084,
   Author = {Depro, B and Timmins, C and O’neil, M},
   Title = {White flight and coming to the nuisance: can residential
             mobility explain environmental injustice?},
   Journal = {Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource
             Economists},
   Volume = {2},
   Number = {3},
   Pages = {439-468},
   Publisher = {University of Chicago Press},
   Year = {2015},
   Month = {September},
   ISSN = {2333-5955},
   url = {http://www.jstor.org/stable/10.1086/682716},
   Abstract = {Effective environmental justice (EJ) policy requires an
             understanding of the economic and social forces that
             determine the correlation between race, income, and
             pollution exposure. We show how the traditional approach
             used in many EJ analyses cannot identify nuisance-driven
             residential mobility. We develop an alternative strategy
             that overcomes this problem and implement it using data on
             air toxics from Los Angeles County, California, USA.
             Differences in estimated willingness to pay for cleaner air
             across race groups support the residential mobility
             explanation. Our results suggest that Hispanics may dislike
             cancer risk but be less willing to trade other forms of
             consumption to avoid it. As a result, household mobility
             responses may work against policies designed to address
             inequitable siting decisions for facilities with
             environmental health risks.},
   Doi = {10.1086/682716},
   Key = {fds239084}
}

@article{fds239085,
   Author = {Kuminoff, NV and Schoellman, T and Timmins, C},
   Title = {Environmental Regulations and the Welfare Effects of Job
             Layoffs in the United States: A Spatial Approach},
   Journal = {Review of Environmental Economics and Policy},
   Volume = {9},
   Number = {2},
   Pages = {198-218},
   Publisher = {University of Chicago Press},
   Year = {2015},
   Month = {July},
   ISSN = {1750-6816},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/reep/rev006},
   Doi = {10.1093/reep/rev006},
   Key = {fds239085}
}

@article{fds239089,
   Author = {Spiller, E and Stephens, H and Timmins, C and Smith,
             A},
   Title = {The Effect of Gasoline Taxes and Public Transit Investments
             on Driving Patterns},
   Journal = {Environmental and Resource Economics},
   Volume = {59},
   Number = {4},
   Pages = {633-657},
   Publisher = {Springer Nature},
   Year = {2014},
   Month = {December},
   ISSN = {0924-6460},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10640-013-9753-9},
   Abstract = {This paper analyzes how driving patterns are affected by
             gasoline taxes and the availability of a substitute for
             driving—public transportation. We develop a measure of
             transportation substitutability based on the difference
             between individuals’ predicted commute times by private
             and public transit, conditional upon their demographic
             characteristics and geographic location. Improved
             substitutability decreases annual vehicle miles traveled
             (VMT) by inducing modal shifts to public transit, though
             gasoline taxes are found to have a much larger impact on
             VMT. Our results imply that a policy that raises gasoline
             taxes and recycles the revenues into public transit
             improvements can have even larger impacts on driving
             patterns than either policy alone.},
   Doi = {10.1007/s10640-013-9753-9},
   Key = {fds239089}
}

@article{fds239088,
   Author = {Kuminoff, NV and Smith, VK and Timmins, C},
   Title = {The new economics of equilibrium sorting and policy
             evaluation using housing markets},
   Journal = {Journal of Economic Literature},
   Volume = {51},
   Number = {4},
   Pages = {1007-1062},
   Publisher = {American Economic Association},
   Year = {2013},
   Month = {December},
   ISSN = {0022-0515},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/jel.51.4.1007},
   Abstract = {Households "sort" across neighborhoods according to their
             wealth and their preferences for public goods, social
             characteristics, and commuting opportunities. The
             aggregation of these individual choices in markets and in
             other institutions influences the supply of amenities and
             local public goods. Pollution, congestion, and the quality
             of public education are examples. Over the past decade,
             advances in economic models of this sorting process have led
             to a new framework that promises to alter the ways we
             conceptualize the policy evaluation process in the future.
             These "equilibrium sorting" models use the properties of
             market equilibria, together with information on household
             behavior, to infer structural parameters that characterize
             preference heterogeneity. The results can be used to develop
             theoretically consistent predictions for the welfare
             implications of future policy changes. Analysis is not
             confined to marginal effects or a partial equilibrium
             setting. Nor is it limited to prices and quantities. Sorting
             models can integrate descriptions of how nonmarket goods are
             generated, estimate how they affect decision making, and, in
             turn, predict how they will be affected by future policies
             targeting prices or quantities. Conversely, sorting models
             can predict how equilibrium prices and quantities will be
             affected by policies that target product quality,
             information, or amenities generated by the sorting process.
             These capabilities are just beginning to be understood and
             used in applied research. This survey article aims to
             synthesize the state of knowledge on equilibrium sorting,
             the new possibilities for policy analysis, and the
             conceptual and empirical challenges that define the
             frontiers of the literature. ( JEL C63, D04, E61, H41, R23,
             R31, R38). © Copyright 2013 by the American Economic
             Association.},
   Doi = {10.1257/jel.51.4.1007},
   Key = {fds239088}
}

@article{fds239090,
   Author = {Ellickson, PB and Houghton, S and Timmins, C},
   Title = {Estimating network economies in retail chains: A revealed
             preference approach},
   Journal = {The Rand Journal of Economics},
   Volume = {44},
   Number = {2},
   Pages = {169-193},
   Publisher = {WILEY},
   Year = {2013},
   Month = {June},
   ISSN = {0741-6261},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1756-2171.12016},
   Abstract = {We measure the effects of chain economies, business
             stealing, and heterogeneous firms' comparative advantages in
             the discount retail industry. Traditional entry models are
             ill suited for this high-dimensional problem of strategic
             interaction. Building upon recently developed profit
             inequality techniques, our model admits any number of
             potential rivals and stores per location, an endogenous
             distribution network, and unobserved (to the econometrician)
             location attributes that may cause firms to cluster their
             stores. In an application, we find that Wal-Mart benefits
             most from local chain economies, whereas Target shows a
             greater ability to respond to rival competition. Kmart
             exhibits neither of these strengths. We explore these
             results with counterfactual simulations highlighting these
             offsetting effects and find that local chain economies play
             an important role in securing Wal-Mart's industry leader
             status. © 2013, RAND.},
   Doi = {10.1111/1756-2171.12016},
   Key = {fds239090}
}

@article{fds239091,
   Author = {Gamper-Rabindran, S and Timmins, C},
   Title = {Does cleanup of hazardous waste sites raise housing values?
             Evidence of spatially localized benefits},
   Journal = {Journal of Environmental Economics and Management},
   Volume = {65},
   Number = {3},
   Pages = {345-360},
   Year = {2013},
   Month = {May},
   ISSN = {0095-0696},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2012.12.001},
   Abstract = {Economists often rely on publicly available data provided at
             coarse geographical resolution to value spatially localized
             amenities. We propose a simple refinement to the hedonic
             method that accommodates this reality: specifically, we
             measure localized benefits from the cleanup of hazardous
             waste sites at the sub-census tract level by examining the
             entire within-tract housing value distribution, rather than
             simply focusing on the tract median. Our point estimates
             indicate that the cleanup leads to larger appreciation in
             house prices at the lower percentiles of the within-tract
             house value distribution than at higher percentiles. Though
             not statistically different from one another, the estimates
             are monotonically ordered from 24.4% at the 10th percentile,
             20.8% at the median and 18.7% at the 90th percentile,
             respectively. We confirm these results in two ways. First,
             our analysis using restricted access census block data finds
             comparable results that cleanup leads to a 14.7%
             appreciation in the median block-level housing values.
             Second, our analysis of proprietary housing transactions
             data show that cheaper houses within a census tract are
             indeed more likely to be closer to a hazardous waste site,
             explaining the greater impacts they receive from the cleanup
             process. © 2012 Elsevier Inc.},
   Doi = {10.1016/j.jeem.2012.12.001},
   Key = {fds239091}
}

@article{fds239092,
   Author = {Deleire, T and Khan, S and Timmins, C},
   Title = {Roy model sorting and nonrandom selection in the valuation
             of a statistical life},
   Journal = {International Economic Review},
   Volume = {54},
   Number = {1},
   Pages = {279-306},
   Publisher = {WILEY},
   Year = {2013},
   Month = {February},
   ISSN = {0020-6598},
   url = {http://gateway.webofknowledge.com/gateway/Gateway.cgi?GWVersion=2&SrcApp=PARTNER_APP&SrcAuth=LinksAMR&KeyUT=WOS:000313987000010&DestLinkType=FullRecord&DestApp=ALL_WOS&UsrCustomerID=47d3190e77e5a3a53558812f597b0b92},
   Abstract = {Wage-hedonics is used to recover the value of a statistical
             life (VSL) by exploiting the fact that workers choosing
             riskier occupations are compensated with a higher wage. Roy
             (Oxford Economic Papers 3 (1951), 135-46) suggests that
             observed wage distributions will be distorted if individuals
             choose jobs according to idiosyncratic returns. We describe
             how this type of sorting biases wage-hedonic VSL estimates
             and implement two new estimation strategies that correct
             that bias. Using data from the Current Population Surveys,
             we recover VSL estimates that are three to four times larger
             than those based on the traditional techniques,
             statistically significant, and robust to a wide array of
             specifications. © (2013) by the Economics Department of the
             University of Pennsylvania and the Osaka University
             Institute of Social and Economic Research
             Association.},
   Doi = {10.1111/j.1468-2354.2012.00733.x},
   Key = {fds239092}
}

@article{fds320630,
   Author = {Muehlenbachs, L and Spiller, E and Timmins, CD},
   Title = {Shale Gas Development and Property Values: Differences
             Across Drinking Water Sources},
   Journal = {Economic Research Initiatives at Duke (Erid) Working
             Paper},
   Number = {131},
   Year = {2012},
   Month = {September},
   Abstract = {While shale gas development can result in rapid local
             economic development, negative externalities associated with
             the process may adversely affect the prices of nearby homes.
             We utilize a triple-difference estimator and exploit the
             public water service area boundary in Washington County,
             Pennsylvania to identify the housing capitalization of
             groundwater risk, differentiating it from other
             externalities, lease payments to homeowners, and local
             economic development. We find that proximity to wells
             increases housing values, though risks to groundwater fully
             offset those gains. By itself, groundwater risk reduces
             property values by up to 24 percent.},
   Key = {fds320630}
}

@article{fds239105,
   Author = {Bajari, P and Fruehwirth, JC and Kim, KI and Timmins,
             C},
   Title = {A rational expectations approach to hedonic price
             regressions with time-varying unobserved product attributes:
             The price of pollution},
   Journal = {American Economic Review},
   Volume = {102},
   Number = {5},
   Pages = {1898-1926},
   Publisher = {American Economic Association},
   Year = {2012},
   Month = {August},
   ISSN = {0002-8282},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.102.5.1898},
   Abstract = {We propose a new strategy for a pervasive problem in the
             hedonics literature: recovering hedonic prices in the
             presence of time-varying correlated unobservables. Our
             approach relies on an assumption about home buyer
             rationality, under which prior sales prices can be used to
             control for time-varying unobservable attributes of the
             house or neighborhood. Using housing transactions data from
             California's Bay Area between 1990 and 2006, we apply our
             estimator to recover marginal willingness to pay for
             reductions in three of the EPA's "criteria" air pollutants.
             Our findings suggest that ignoring bias from time-varying
             correlated unobservables considerably understates the
             benefits of a pollution reduction policy.},
   Doi = {10.1257/aer.102.5.1898},
   Key = {fds239105}
}

@article{fds239104,
   Author = {Gamper-Rabindran, S and Timmins, C},
   Title = {Hazardous waste cleanup, neighborhood gentrification, and
             environmental justice: Evidence from restricted access
             census block data},
   Journal = {American Economic Review},
   Volume = {101},
   Number = {3},
   Pages = {620-624},
   Publisher = {American Economic Association},
   Year = {2011},
   Month = {May},
   ISSN = {0002-8282},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.101.3.620},
   Abstract = {We test for residential sorting and changes in neighborhood
             characteristics in response to the cleanup of hazardous
             waste sites using restricted access fine-geographicalresolution
             block data. We examine changes between 1990 and 2000 in
             blocks within 5km of sites that are proposed to the National
             Priority List that fall in a narrow interval of Hazardous
             Ranking Scores, comparing blocks near sites that were
             cleaned with those near sites that were not. Cleanup leads
             to increases in population density and housing unit density;
             increases in mean household income and shares of
             collegeeducated; but also to increases in the shares of
             minorities. © 2011 AEA. The American Economic Association
             is hosted by Vanderbilt University.},
   Doi = {10.1257/aer.101.3.620},
   Key = {fds239104}
}

@article{fds239111,
   Author = {Bayer, P and Khan, S and Timmins, C},
   Title = {Nonparametric identification and estimation in a Roy model
             with common nonpecuniary returns},
   Journal = {Journal of Business & Economic Statistics},
   Volume = {29},
   Number = {2},
   Pages = {201-215},
   Publisher = {Informa UK Limited},
   Year = {2011},
   Month = {April},
   ISSN = {0735-0015},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1198/jbes.2010.08083},
   Abstract = {We consider identification and estimation of a Roy model
             that includes a common nonpecuniary utility component
             associated with each choice alternative. This augmented Roy
             model has broader applications to many polychotomous choice
             problems in addition to occupational sorting. We develop a
             pair of nonparametric estimators for this model, derive
             asymptotics, and illustrate small-sample properties with a
             series of Monte Carlo experiments. We apply one of these
             models to migration behavior and analyze the effect of Roy
             sorting on observed returns to college education. Correcting
             for Roy sorting bias, the returns to a college degree are
             cut in half. This article has supplementary material online.
             © 2011 American Statistical Association.},
   Doi = {10.1198/jbes.2010.08083},
   Key = {fds239111}
}

@article{fds239107,
   Author = {Gamper-Rabindran, S and Khan, S and Timmins, C},
   Title = {The impact of piped water provision on infant mortality in
             Brazil: A quantile panel data approach},
   Journal = {Journal of Development Economics},
   Volume = {92},
   Number = {2},
   Pages = {188-200},
   Publisher = {Elsevier BV},
   Year = {2010},
   Month = {July},
   ISSN = {0304-3878},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/2010 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {We examine the impact of piped water on the under-1 infant
             mortality rate (IMR) in Brazil using a recently developed
             econometric procedure for the estimation of quantile
             treatment effects with panel data. The provision of piped
             water in Brazil is highly correlated with other observable
             and unobservable determinants of IMR - the latter leading to
             an important source of bias. Instruments for piped water
             provision are not readily available, and fixed effects to
             control for time-invariant correlated unobservables are
             invalid in the simple quantile regression framework. Using
             the quantile panel data procedure in Chen and Khan [Chen,
             S., Khan, S., Semiparametric estimation of non-stationary
             censored panel model data models with time-varying factor.
             Econometric Theory 2007; forthcoming], our estimates
             indicate that the provision of piped water reduces infant
             mortality by significantly more at the higher conditional
             quantiles of the IMR distribution than at the lower
             conditional quantiles (except for cases of extreme
             underdevelopment). These results imply that targeting piped
             water intervention toward areas in the upper quantiles of
             the conditional IMR distribution, when accompanied by other
             basic public health inputs, can achieve significantly
             greater reductions in infant mortality. © 2009 Elsevier
             B.V.},
   Doi = {10.1016/j.jdeveco.2009.02.006},
   Key = {fds239107}
}

@article{fds239086,
   Author = {Timmins, C and Schlenker, W},
   Title = {Reduced-Form Versus Structural Modeling in Environmental and
             Resource Economics},
   Journal = {Annual Review of Resource Economics},
   Volume = {1},
   Number = {1},
   Pages = {351-380},
   Publisher = {ANNUAL REVIEWS},
   Year = {2009},
   Month = {October},
   ISSN = {1941-1340},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1146/annurev.resource.050708.144119},
   Abstract = {<jats:p> We contrast structural and reduced form empirical
             studies in environmental and resource economics. Both
             methodologies have their own context-specific advantages and
             disadvantages, and should be viewed as complements, not
             substitutes. Structural models typically require a
             theoretical model and explicit assumptions about structural
             errors in order to recover the parameters of behavioral
             functions. These estimates may be required to measure
             general equilibrium welfare effects or to simulate intricate
             feedback loops between natural and economic processes.
             However, many of the assumptions used to recover structural
             estimates are untestable. The goal of reduced form studies
             is, conversely, to recover key parameters of interest using
             exogenous within-sample variation with as few structural
             assumptions as possible—reducing reliance on these
             assumptions assists in establishing causality in the
             relationship of interest. Reduced-form studies do, however,
             require assumptions of their own, e.g., the (quasi)
             randomness of an experiment with no spillover effects on the
             control group. </jats:p>},
   Doi = {10.1146/annurev.resource.050708.144119},
   Key = {fds239086}
}

@misc{lall_connecting_2009,
   Author = {Lall, SV and Timmins, C and Yu, S},
   Title = {Connecting lagging and leading regions: The role of labor
             mobility},
   Journal = {Brookings Wharton Papers on Urban Affairs},
   Volume = {2009},
   Pages = {151-174},
   Booktitle = {Brookings-Wharton Papers on Urban Affairs},
   Publisher = {The Brookings Institution},
   Address = {Washington, D.C.},
   Year = {2009},
   Month = {September},
   ISSN = {1528-7084},
   url = {http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=eoh&AN=1036301&site=ehost-live&scope=site},
   Abstract = {How can policies improve the welfare of people in
             economically lagging regions of countries? Should policies
             help jobs follow people? Or should they enable people to
             follow jobs? In most countries, market forces have
             encouraged the geographic concentration of people and
             economic activities--policies that try to offset these
             forces to encourage balanced economic growth have largely
             been unsuccessful. However, policies that help people get
             closer to economic density have improved individual welfare.
             In this paper, the authors examine the migration decisions
             of working-age Brazilians and find that the pull of higher
             wages in leading regions has a strong influence on the
             decision to migrate. However, many people are also"pushed"to
             migrate, starved of access to basic public services such as
             clean water and sanitation in their hometowns. Although
             migration is welfare-improving for these individuals, the
             economy may end up worse off as these migrants are more
             likely to add to congestion costs in cities than to
             contribute to agglomeration benefits. Encouraging human
             capital formation can stimulate labor mobility for economic
             gain; and improving access to and quality of basic services
             in lagging regions will directly improve welfare as well as
             reduce the type of migration motivated by the search for
             life-supporting basic services.},
   Key = {lall_connecting_2009}
}

@article{Bayer09,
   Author = {Bayer, P and Keohane, N and Timmins, C},
   Title = {Migration and hedonic valuation: The case of air
             quality},
   Journal = {Journal of Environmental Economics and Management},
   Volume = {58},
   Number = {1},
   Pages = {1-14},
   Publisher = {Elsevier BV},
   Year = {2009},
   Month = {July},
   ISSN = {0095-0696},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/2025 Duke open
             access},
   Keywords = {Discrete choice models • Migration costs •
             Particulate matter • residential sorting •
             Valuation of air qualitly • Wage-hedonic
             models},
   Abstract = {Conventional hedonic techniques for estimating the value of
             local amenities rely on the assumption that households move
             freely among locations. We show that when moving is costly,
             the variation in housing prices and wages across locations
             may no longer reflect the value of differences in local
             amenities. We develop an alternative discrete-choice
             approach that models the household location decision
             directly, and we apply it to the case of air quality in US
             metro areas in 1990 and 2000. Because air pollution is
             likely to be correlated with unobservable local
             characteristics such as economic activity, we instrument for
             air quality using the contribution of distant sources to
             local pollution-excluding emissions from local sources,
             which are most likely to be correlated with local
             conditions. Our model yields an estimated elasticity of
             willingness to pay with respect to air quality of 0.34-0.42.
             These estimates imply that the median household would pay
             $149-$185 (in constant 1982-1984 dollars) for a one-unit
             reduction in average ambient concentrations of particulate
             matter. These estimates are three times greater than the
             marginal willingness to pay estimated by a conventional
             hedonic model using the same data. Our results are robust to
             a range of covariates, instrumenting strategies, and
             functional form assumptions. The findings also confirm the
             importance of instrumenting for local air pollution. © 2009
             Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.},
   Doi = {10.1016/j.jeem.2008.08.004},
   Key = {Bayer09}
}

@article{wagner_agglomeration_2009,
   Author = {Wagner, UJ and Timmins, CD},
   Title = {Agglomeration effects in foreign direct investment and the
             pollution haven hypothesis},
   Journal = {Environmental and Resource Economics},
   Volume = {43},
   Number = {2},
   Pages = {231-256},
   Publisher = {Springer Nature},
   Year = {2009},
   Month = {January},
   ISSN = {0924-6460},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/2059 Duke open
             access},
   Keywords = {Air Pollution; Water Pollution; Noise; Hazardous Waste;
             Solid Waste; Recycling Q530, Chemicals; Rubber; Drugs;
             Biotechnology L650, Economic Development: Agriculture;
             Natural Resources; Energy; Environment; Other Primary
             Products O130, Environmental Economics: Government Policy
             Q580, Multinational Firms; International Business F230,
             Other Production and Pricing Analysis R320},
   Abstract = {Does environmental regulation impair international
             competitiveness of pollution-intensive industries to the
             extent that they relocate to countries with less stringent
             regulation, turning those countries into "pollution havens"?
             We test this hypothesis using panel data on outward foreign
             direct investment (FDI) flows of various industries in the
             German manufacturing sector and account for several
             econometric issues that have been ignored in previous
             studies. Most importantly, we demonstrate that externalities
             associated with FDI agglomeration can bias estimates away
             from finding a pollution haven effect if omitted from the
             analysis. We include the stock of inward FDI as a proxy for
             agglomeration and employ a GMM estimator to control for
             endogenous time-varying determinants of FDI flows.
             Furthermore, we propose a difference estimator based on the
             least polluting industry to break the possible correlation
             between environmental regulatory stringency and unobservable
             attributes of FDI recipients in the cross-section. When
             accounting for these issues we find robust evidence of a
             pollution haven effect for the chemical industry. © 2008
             Springer Science+Business Media B.V.},
   Doi = {10.1007/s10640-008-9236-6},
   Key = {wagner_agglomeration_2009}
}

@article{fds239106,
   Author = {Pattanayak, SK and Ross, MT and Depro, BM and Bauch, SC and Timmins, C and Wendland, KJ and Alger, K},
   Title = {Climate change and conservation in Brazil: CGE evaluation of
             health and wealth impacts},
   Journal = {The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy},
   Volume = {9},
   Number = {2},
   Publisher = {WALTER DE GRUYTER GMBH},
   Year = {2009},
   Month = {January},
   ISSN = {1935-1682},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.2202/1935-1682.2096},
   Abstract = {Ecosystem services are public goods that frequently
             constitute the only source of capital for the poor, who lack
             political voice. As a result, provision of ecosystem
             services is sub-optimal and estimation of their values is
             complicated. We examine how econometric estimation can feed
             computable general equilibrium (CGE) modeling to estimate
             health-related ecosystem values. Against a back drop of
             climate change, we analyze the Brazilian policy to expand
             National Forests (FLONAS) by 50 million hectares. Because
             these major environmental changes can generate spillovers in
             other sectors, we develop and use a CGE model that focuses
             on land and labor markets. Compared to climate change and
             deforestation in the baseline, the FLONAS scenario suggests
             relatively small declines in GDP, output (including
             agriculture) and other macro indicators. Urban households
             will experience declines in their welfare because they own
             most of the capital and land, which allows them to capture
             most of the deforestation benefits. In contrast, even though
             rural households have fewer opportunities for subsistence
             agriculture and face additional competition with other rural
             agricultural workers for more limited employment, their
             welfare improves due to health benefits from conservation of
             nearby forests. The efficiency vs. equity tradeoffs implied
             by the FLONAS scenario suggests that health-related
             ecosystem services will be underprovided if the rural poor
             are politically weaker than the urban rich. In conclusion,
             we briefly discuss the pros and cons of the CGE strategy for
             valuing ecosystem-mediated health benefits and evaluating
             contemporary policies on climate change mitigation.
             Copyright © 2009 The Berkeley Electronic Press. All rights
             reserved.},
   Doi = {10.2202/1935-1682.2096},
   Key = {fds239106}
}

@article{li_do_2009,
   Author = {Timmins, CD and Li, S and von Haefen, R},
   Title = {How Do Gas Prices Affect Fleet Fuel Economy?},
   Journal = {American Economic Journal: Economic Policy},
   Volume = {1},
   Number = {2},
   Pages = {113-137},
   Publisher = {American Economic Association},
   Year = {2009},
   ISSN = {1945-7812},
   url = {http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=eoh&AN=1051386&site=ehost-live&scope=site},
   Keywords = {Business Taxes and Subsidies including sales and value-added
             {(VAT)} H250, Industry Studies: Manufacturing: Other L690,
             Mining, Extraction, and Refining: Hydrocarbon Fuels L710,
             Production, Pricing, and Market Structure; Size Distribution
             of Firms L110},
   Abstract = {Exploiting a rich dataset of passenger vehicle registrations
             in 20 US MSAs from 1997 to 2005, we examine the effects of
             gasoline prices on the automotive fleet's composition. We
             find that high gasoline prices affect fleet fuel economy
             through two channels: shifting new auto purchases towards
             more fuel-efficient vehicles, and speeding the scrappage of
             older, less fuel-efficient used vehicles. Policy simulations
             suggest that a 10 percent increase in gasoline prices from
             2005 levels will generate a 0.22 percent increase in fleet
             fuel economy in the short run and a 2.04 percent increase in
             the long run.},
   Doi = {10.1257/pol.1.2.113},
   Key = {li_do_2009}
}

@article{timmins_revealed_2007,
   Author = {Timmins, C and Murdock, J},
   Title = {A revealed preference approach to the measurement of
             congestion in travel cost models},
   Journal = {Journal of Environmental Economics and Management},
   Volume = {53},
   Number = {2},
   Pages = {230-249},
   Publisher = {Elsevier BV},
   Year = {2007},
   Month = {March},
   ISSN = {0095-0696},
   url = {http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=eoh&AN=0902859&site=ehost-live&scope=site},
   Keywords = {Recreational Aspects of Natural Resources Q260, Renewable
             Resources and Conservation: Fishery; Aquaculture Q220,
             Transportation: Demand, Supply, and Congestion; Safety and
             Accidents; Transportation Noise R410},
   Abstract = {Travel cost models are regularly used to determine the value
             of recreational sites or particular site characteristics,
             yet congestion, a key site attribute, is often excluded from
             such analyses. One reason for this omission is that
             congestion is determined in equilibrium by the process of
             individuals sorting across sites and thus presents
             significant endogeneity problems. This paper illustrates
             this source of endogeneity, describes how previous research
             has dealt with it using stated preference techniques, and
             describes an instrumental variables approach to address it
             in a revealed preference context. We demonstrate that
             failing to address the endogeneity of congestion leads one
             to dramatically understate its costs. We apply our technique
             to the valuation of a large recreational fishing site in
             Wisconsin (Lake Winnebago) which, if eliminated, would
             induce significant re-sorting of anglers amongst remaining
             sites. Ignoring congestion leads to an understatement of the
             lake's value by more than 50%. © 2006 Elsevier Inc. All
             rights reserved.},
   Doi = {10.1016/j.jeem.2006.08.002},
   Key = {timmins_revealed_2007}
}

@article{bayer_estimating_2007,
   Author = {Bayer, P and Timmins, C},
   Title = {Estimating equilibrium models of sorting across
             locations},
   Journal = {The Economic Journal},
   Volume = {117},
   Number = {518},
   Pages = {353-374},
   Publisher = {Oxford University Press (OUP)},
   Year = {2007},
   Month = {March},
   ISSN = {0013-0133},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/2026 Duke open
             access},
   Keywords = {Other Production and Pricing Analysis R320, Urban, Rural,
             and Regional Economics: Housing Demand R210, Urban, Rural,
             and Regional Economics: Regional Migration; Regional Labor
             Markets; Population; Neighborhood Characteristics
             R230},
   Abstract = {While there is growing interest in measuring the size and
             scope of local spillovers, it is well understood that such
             spillovers cannot be distinguished from unobservable local
             attributes using solely the observed location decisions of
             individuals or firms. We propose an empirical strategy for
             recovering estimates of spillovers in the presence of
             unobserved local attributes for a broadly applicable class
             of equilibrium sorting models. Our approach relies on an IV
             strategy derived from the internal logic of the sorting
             model itself. We show practically how the strategy is
             implemented, provide intuition for our instruments, discuss
             the role of effective choice-set variation in identifying
             the model, and carry-out a series of Monte Carlo simulations
             to demonstrate performance in small samples. © 2007 The
             Author(s). Journal compilation Royal Economic Society
             2007.},
   Doi = {10.1111/j.1468-0297.2007.02021.x},
   Key = {bayer_estimating_2007}
}

@article{timmins_if_2007,
   Author = {Timmins, C},
   Title = {If you cannot take the heat, get out of the cerrado...
             Recovering the equilibrium amenity cost of nonmarginal
             climate change in Brazil},
   Journal = {Journal of Regional Science},
   Volume = {47},
   Number = {1},
   Pages = {1-25},
   Publisher = {WILEY},
   Year = {2007},
   Month = {January},
   ISSN = {0022-4146},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/2036 Duke open
             access},
   Keywords = {Climate; Natural Disasters; Global Warming Q540, Economic
             Development: Agriculture; Natural Resources; Energy;
             Environment; Other Primary Products O130, Economic
             Development: Regional, Urban, and Rural Analyses O180,
             Urban, Rural, and Regional Economics: Regional Migration;
             Regional Labor Markets; Population; Neighborhood
             Characteristics R230, Valuation of Environmental Effects
             Q510},
   Abstract = {This paper presents an empirical technique for valuing large
             changes in nonmarketed local attributes (e.g., climate
             amenities) without data describing prices of locally traded
             commodities like housing. A model of endogenous sorting is
             used to identify individuals' indirect utility functions,
             from which the value of the change in the local attribute is
             recovered while accounting for equilibrium impacts on
             markets for labor and locally traded commodities. Annual
             amenity costs of Brazilian climate change are estimated to
             be between $1.6 and $8.1 billion for a moderate climate
             change scenario, depending upon the role of migration costs.
             © Blackwell Publishing, Inc. 2007.},
   Doi = {10.1111/j.1467-9787.2007.00497.x},
   Key = {timmins_if_2007}
}

@article{timmins_estimating_2006,
   Author = {Timmins, C},
   Title = {Estimating spatial differences in the Brazilian cost of
             living with household location choices},
   Journal = {Journal of Development Economics},
   Volume = {80},
   Number = {1},
   Pages = {59-83},
   Publisher = {Elsevier BV},
   Year = {2006},
   Month = {June},
   ISSN = {0304-3878},
   url = {http://search.ebscohost.com/login.aspx?direct=true&db=eoh&AN=0870767&site=ehost-live&scope=site},
   Keywords = {Consumer Economics: Empirical Analysis D120, Economic
             Development: Human Resources; Human Development; Income
             Distribution; Migration O150, Other Production and Pricing
             Analysis R320, Urban, Rural, and Regional Economics:
             Regional Migration; Regional Labor Markets; Population;
             Neighborhood Characteristics R230},
   Abstract = {This paper uses a model of optimal household residential
             decisions to construct a comprehensive "true" spatial cost
             of living index with readily available Brazilian census
             data. We find evidence of a decreasing or U-shaped
             relationship (differing with education level and region)
             between the cost of living and urbanization, suggesting that
             both market disintegration and congestion play roles in
             raising costs. Controlling for spatial differences in the
             cost of living is shown to have important consequences for
             the determinants of poverty and (contrary to many previous
             results) to increase income inequality. © 2005 Elsevier
             B.V. All rights reserved.},
   Doi = {10.1016/j.jdeveco.2005.02.006},
   Key = {timmins_estimating_2006}
}

@article{Timmins06a,
   Author = {Timmins, C},
   Title = {Endogenous land use and the Ricardian valuation of climate
             change},
   Journal = {Environmental and Resource Economics},
   Volume = {33},
   Number = {1},
   Pages = {119-142},
   Publisher = {Springer Nature},
   Year = {2006},
   Month = {January},
   ISSN = {0924-6460},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10640-005-2646-9},
   Keywords = {Endogenous land • Ricardian technique},
   Abstract = {The Ricardian technique uses cross-sectional variation in
             the capitalized value of climate in land to infer the
             agricultural costs or benefits of dynamic climate change.
             While a practical approach for predicting the consequences
             of global warming with readily available data, it may yield
             biased results when land-use decisions depend on the climate
             attributes being valued and when land has unobserved
             attributes that differ with the use to which it is put. This
             paper illustrates the conditions under which such a bias
             will occur, describes an empirical model that corrects for
             it, and estimates that model with agricultural census data
             from Brazil. The approach, moreover, allows constraints on
             adjustment to be explicitly incorporated into the Ricardian
             framework, relaxing one of that technique's most conspicuous
             assumptions. © Springer 2006.},
   Doi = {10.1007/s10640-005-2646-9},
   Key = {Timmins06a}
}

@article{Nou05,
   Author = {Nou, J and Timmins, C},
   Title = {How do changes in welfare law affect domestic violence? An
             analysis of Connecticut towns, 1990-2000},
   Journal = {The Journal of Legal Studies},
   Volume = {34},
   Number = {2},
   Pages = {445-469},
   Publisher = {University of Chicago Press},
   Year = {2005},
   Month = {June},
   ISSN = {0047-2530},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/429847},
   Keywords = {Domestic violence • Time limits • Welfare reform
             • Welfare to work • Work mandates},
   Abstract = {The 1996 Personal Responsibility and Work Opportunity
             Reconciliation Act transformed welfare from an ongoing cash
             assistance program by restricting participation through time
             limits and emphasizing rapid entrance into the labor force.
             Changes in welfare dependency induced by these legal reforms
             had the potential to impact rates of domestic violence.
             Using decennial census, welfare caseload, and police report
             data, this paper investigates the introduction of time
             limits and work mandates across Connecticut towns. For a
             variety of reasons, Connecticut proves to be an ideal
             laboratory from which to obtain evidence. We find that rates
             of domestic violence fell in Connecticut with the passage of
             the new welfare law, especially in towns most subject to the
             law's provisions. Using Federal Bureau of Investigation
             Uniform Crime Report data, we also find evidence that such
             results hold independent of the reform's effects on other
             personal crimes and crimes in general. © 2005 by The
             University of Chicago. All rights reserved.},
   Doi = {10.1086/429847},
   Key = {Nou05}
}

@article{Bayer05,
   Author = {Bayer, P and Timmins, C},
   Title = {On the equilibrium properties of locational sorting
             models},
   Journal = {Journal of Urban Economics},
   Volume = {57},
   Number = {3},
   Pages = {462-477},
   Publisher = {Elsevier BV},
   Year = {2005},
   Month = {May},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jue.2004.12.008},
   Keywords = {Agglomeration • Congestion • Discrete choice
             models • Economic geography • Endogenous sorting
             • Local spillovers • Natural advantage •
             random utility • Social interactions},
   Abstract = {Important to many models of location choice is the role of
             local interactions or spillovers, whereby the payoffs from
             choosing a location depend in part on the number or
             attributes of other individuals or firms that choose the
             same or nearby locations in equilibrium. This paper develops
             the equilibrium properties of a broadly applicable and
             readily estimable class of sorting models that allow
             location decisions to depend on both fixed local attributes
             (including unobserved attributes) and local interactions,
             describes the conditions under which equilibria exist and
             are unique, and provides a test for uniqueness in empirical
             analyses of sorting equilibrium. © 2005 Elsevier Inc. All
             rights reserved.},
   Doi = {10.1016/j.jue.2004.12.008},
   Key = {Bayer05}
}

@article{Timmins05,
   Author = {Timmins, C},
   Title = {Estimable equilibrium models of locational sorting and their
             role in development economics},
   Journal = {Journal of Economic Geography},
   Volume = {5},
   Number = {1},
   Pages = {83-100},
   Publisher = {Oxford University Press (OUP)},
   Year = {2005},
   Month = {January},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/jnlecg/lbh055},
   Keywords = {Agglomeration • Congestion • Discrete choice
             models • Economic geography • Endogenous location
             choice • Local spillovers • Natural
             advantage},
   Abstract = {Geography plays a prominent role in many problems in
             development economics - directly in analyses of the spatial
             distribution of important variables like poverty and
             productivity, and indirectly through the role of local
             spillovers in economic growth. Empirical work on these
             topics is complicated by the fact that the behavioral
             consequences of such spillovers cannot be distinguished from
             those of unobservable local attributes using only the
             observed location decisions of individuals or firms. This
             problem can be solved with an instrumental variables
             strategy derived from the internal logic of a structural
             model of residential sorting. We show practically how the
             strategy is implemented, provide intuition for the
             instruments and econometric identification, demonstrate how
             traditional techniques overstate agglomeration
             externalities, and use the model to value changes in
             spillovers from urban centers. © Oxford University Press
             2005; all rights reserved.},
   Doi = {10.1093/jnlecg/lbh055},
   Key = {Timmins05}
}

@article{fds239095,
   Author = {Timmins, C},
   Title = {Demand-Side Technology Standards Under Inefficient Pricing
             Regimes: Are They Effective Water Conservation Tools in the
             Long-Run?},
   Journal = {Environmental and Resource Economics},
   Volume = {26},
   Number = {1},
   Pages = {107-124},
   Year = {2003},
   Month = {September},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1023/A:1025689706396},
   Abstract = {When price-setting regulators have objectives other than
             maximizing social surplus, the conservation potential of
             demand-side technology standards can be significantly
             diminished. This paper demonstrates this by empirically
             recovering the socially sub-optimal preferences of a group
             of water managers in a groundwater-dependent region of
             California and simulating their inefficient price response
             to the mandated adoption of low-flow appliances by
             homeowners. The resulting reduction in the conservation
             potential of these appliances is quantified, and a modest
             tax is shown to be a relatively cost-effective policy tool
             for conservation. If non-price conservation policies are
             preferred according to equity criteria, the paper suggests
             that, in order to preserve their conservation potential,
             policy-makers should be required to continue to set prices
             as if no technology standards had been introduced.},
   Doi = {10.1023/A:1025689706396},
   Key = {fds239095}
}

@article{fds239093,
   Author = {Timmins, C},
   Title = {Does the median voter consume too much water? Analyzing the
             redistributive role of residential water
             bills},
   Journal = {National Tax Journal},
   Volume = {55},
   Number = {4},
   Pages = {687-702},
   Publisher = {National Tax Association},
   Year = {2002},
   Month = {January},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/2042 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {According to allocative efficiency criteria, water in the
             American West is often underpriced in urban sales. The
             political-economic process that motivates municipal managers
             to impose the resulting deadweight losses on their
             constituencies is analyzed with a median voter model of
             choice between alternative municipal revenue sources. The
             implications of this model are tested empirically, and the
             results confirm the conclusions of previous empirical
             research by suggesting that cities with more skewed income
             distributions tend to engage in more redistributive
             activities than other conditionally similar
             communities.},
   Doi = {10.17310/ntj.2002.4.02},
   Key = {fds239093}
}

@article{fds239094,
   Author = {Timmins, C},
   Title = {Measuring the dynamic efficiency costs of regulators'
             preferences: Municipal water utilities in the Arid
             West},
   Journal = {Econometrica},
   Volume = {70},
   Number = {2},
   Pages = {603-629},
   Publisher = {The Econometric Society},
   Year = {2002},
   Month = {January},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/1868 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {Evidence suggests that municipal water utility
             administrators in the western US price water significantly
             below its marginal cost and, in so doing, inefficiently
             exploit aquifer stocks and induce social surplus losses.
             This paper empirically identifies the objective function of
             those managers, measures the deadweight losses resulting
             from their price-discounting decisions, and recovers the
             efficient water pricing policy function from counterfactual
             experiments. In doing so, the estimation uses a
             "continuous-but-constrained-control" version of a nested
             fixed-point algorithm in order to measure the important
             intertemporal consequences of groundwater pricing
             decisions.},
   Doi = {10.1111/1468-0262.00297},
   Key = {fds239094}
}


%% Chapters in Books   
@misc{fds360067,
   Author = {Liang, W and Song, R and Timmins, C},
   Title = {The Role of Migration Costs in Residential
             Sorting},
   Pages = {251-283},
   Booktitle = {Urban Book Series},
   Year = {2021},
   Month = {January},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-74544-8_4},
   Abstract = {Economists generally employ two ‘revealed preference’
             approaches to measure households’ preferences for
             non-market amenities—the hedonic and equilibrium sorting
             models. The conventional hedonic model assumes free mobility
             across space. Violation of this assumption can bias the
             estimates of household willingness to pay for local
             amenities. Mobility constraints are more easily handled by
             the sorting framework. In this chapter, we examine the role
             of migration costs in household residential sorting and
             apply these two models to estimate the willingness to pay
             for clean air in the USA and China. Our results demonstrate
             that ignoring mobility costs in spatial sorting will
             underestimate the implicit value of non-market amenities in
             both countries. Such a downward bias is larger in developing
             countries, such as China, where migration costs are
             higher.},
   Doi = {10.1007/978-3-030-74544-8_4},
   Key = {fds360067}
}

@misc{fds349758,
   Author = {Moi, T},
   Title = {Introduction},
   Volume = {4},
   Pages = {iii},
   Booktitle = {Camille The Lady of the Camellias, by Alexandre Dumas
             Fils},
   Publisher = {Signet Classics},
   Year = {2003},
   ISBN = {0451529200},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/693389},
   Abstract = {With a new introduction, this Signet Classic is the only
             available paperback edition of Camille, the instantly-famous
             story of passion versus class that remains as timeless as
             love itself.},
   Doi = {10.1086/693389},
   Key = {fds349758}
}


%% Other   
@misc{fds210363,
   Author = {C.D. Timmins},
   Title = {Course Syllabus for Econ 881: "Hedonics and Non-Market
             Valuation and Equilibrium Sorting"},
   Year = {2012},
   Key = {fds210363}
}

@misc{fds210364,
   Author = {C.D. Timmins},
   Title = {Course Syllabus for Econ 439/Enviro 363: "Economics of the
             Environment"},
   Year = {2012},
   Key = {fds210364}
}


Duke University * Arts & Sciences * Economics * Faculty * Research * Staff * Master's * Ph.D. * Reload * Login