Economics Faculty Database
Economics
Arts & Sciences
Duke University

 HOME > Arts & Sciences > Economics > Faculty    Search Help Login pdf version printable version 

Publications of Lori S. Bennear    :chronological  alphabetical  combined listing:

%% Books   
@book{fds328284,
   Author = {Wiener, J},
   Title = {Policy Shock: Recalibrating Risk and Regulation after Oil
             Spills, Nuclear Accidents, and Financial
             Crises},
   Publisher = {Cambridge University Press},
   Editor = {Balleisen, EJ and Wiener, J and Krawiec, K and Bennear,
             L},
   Year = {2017},
   Month = {November},
   ISBN = {978-1107140219},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/9781316492635},
   Doi = {10.1017/9781316492635},
   Key = {fds328284}
}


%% Papers Published   
@article{fds371155,
   Author = {Baker, J and Bennear, L and Olmstead, S},
   Title = {Does Information Disclosure Reduce Drinking Water Violations
             in the United States?},
   Journal = {Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource
             Economists},
   Volume = {10},
   Number = {3},
   Pages = {787-818},
   Year = {2023},
   Month = {May},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/722619},
   Abstract = {The 1996 Safe Drinking Water Act Amendments required
             community water systems to disclose violations of drinking
             water standards to their customers in annual water quality
             reports. We explore the impact of three methods of
             disclosure on health-based drinking water quality violations
             using a matching and differences-in-differences framework
             with a national data set of drinking water quality
             violations from 1990 to 2001. We find that this information
             disclosure requirement reduced drinking water violations
             significantly and that the primary effect of disclosure on
             violations persists for at least four years after policy
             implementation. We find no evidence, however, that water
             systems trade these potentially more salient violation
             reductions for potentially less salient reductions in
             violations of other standards, nor do we find any evidence
             that water systems responded differentially to disclosure
             based on the demo-graphic or political characteristics of
             their customers.},
   Doi = {10.1086/722619},
   Key = {fds371155}
}

@article{fds367815,
   Author = {Bennear, LS},
   Title = {Energy Justice, Decarbonization, and the Clean Energy
             Transformation},
   Journal = {Annual Review of Resource Economics},
   Volume = {14},
   Pages = {647-668},
   Year = {2022},
   Month = {January},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1146/annurev-resource-111920-022328},
   Abstract = {Addressing climate change will require significant
             reductions in carbon emissions. Decarbonization will likely
             lead to increases in energy prices, which are regressive.
             Poorer households spend a higher percentage of income on
             energy and also have less access to energy efficient options
             in housing, transportation (including electric vehicles),
             and household durables. This review summarizes the state of
             knowledge on the energy justice implications of the clean
             energy transformation along four dimensions¤mdash¤production
             of energy, energy insecurity/energy poverty, access to clean
             energy technologies, and impacts of policy instrument
             choices for achieving decarbonization. Along each dimension
             there is evidence of greater negative impacts on
             lower-income households and on Black, Indigenous, and people
             of color (BIPOC) households, even controlling for income.
             But there is also evidence that these impacts can be
             mitigated through policy choices. Together these findings
             highlight that centering justice concerns in policy debates
             is critical for a just and clean energy transformation.},
   Doi = {10.1146/annurev-resource-111920-022328},
   Key = {fds367815}
}

@article{fds360663,
   Author = {Bennear, LS and Wiener, JB},
   Title = {Institutional Roles and Goals for Retrospective Regulatory
             Analysis},
   Journal = {Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis},
   Volume = {12},
   Number = {3},
   Pages = {466-493},
   Year = {2021},
   Month = {January},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/bca.2021.10},
   Abstract = {Despite repeated calls for retrospective regulatory review
             by every President since the 1970s, progress on implementing
             such reviews has been slow. We argue that part of the
             explanation for the slow progress to date stems from
             misalignment between the goals of regulatory review and the
             institutional framework used for the review. We define three
             distinct goals of regulatory review - the rule relevance
             goal, the rule improvement goal, and the regulatory learning
             goal. We then examine the text of the Presidential Executive
             Orders and major Congressional legislation addressing
             retrospective review, and document which goals were targeted
             and which institutions were used to conduct the reviews. We
             find that the U.S. federal government has almost always
             sought review of one rule at a time, conducted by the agency
             that issued or promulgated the rule and that these reviews
             tend to focus on rule relevance and costs. This
             institutional framework for retrospective review - one rule,
             assessed by the promulgating agency, focused on relevance
             and cost - is only well-suited to a narrow interpretation of
             the rule improvement goal. We then review alternative
             institutional structures that could better meet the rule
             improvement goal and the broader regulatory learning goal
             across multiple rules and agencies, and we offer
             recommendations for developing new guidance and institutions
             to promote multiagency regulatory learning.},
   Doi = {10.1017/bca.2021.10},
   Key = {fds360663}
}

@article{fds324102,
   Author = {Smith, MD and Oglend, A and Kirkpatrick, AJ and Asche, F and Bennear,
             LS and Craig, JK and Nance, JM},
   Title = {Seafood prices reveal impacts of a major ecological
             disturbance.},
   Journal = {Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the
             United States of America},
   Volume = {114},
   Number = {7},
   Pages = {1512-1517},
   Year = {2017},
   Month = {February},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1617948114},
   Abstract = {Coastal hypoxia (dissolved oxygen ≤ 2 mg/L) is a growing
             problem worldwide that threatens marine ecosystem services,
             but little is known about economic effects on fisheries.
             Here, we provide evidence that hypoxia causes economic
             impacts on a major fishery. Ecological studies of hypoxia
             and marine fauna suggest multiple mechanisms through which
             hypoxia can skew a population's size distribution toward
             smaller individuals. These mechanisms produce sharp
             predictions about changes in seafood markets. Hypoxia is
             hypothesized to decrease the quantity of large shrimp
             relative to small shrimp and increase the price of large
             shrimp relative to small shrimp. We test these hypotheses
             using time series of size-based prices. Naive quantity-based
             models using treatment/control comparisons in hypoxic and
             nonhypoxic areas produce null results, but we find strong
             evidence of the hypothesized effects in the relative prices:
             Hypoxia increases the relative price of large shrimp
             compared with small shrimp. The effects of fuel prices
             provide supporting evidence. Empirical models of fishing
             effort and bioeconomic simulations explain why quantifying
             effects of hypoxia on fisheries using quantity data has been
             inconclusive. Specifically, spatial-dynamic feedbacks across
             the natural system (the fish stock) and human system (the
             mobile fishing fleet) confound "treated" and "control"
             areas. Consequently, analyses of price data, which rely on a
             market counterfactual, are able to reveal effects of the
             ecological disturbance that are obscured in quantity data.
             Our results are an important step toward quantifying the
             economic value of reduced upstream nutrient loading in the
             Mississippi Basin and are broadly applicable to other
             coupled human-natural systems.},
   Doi = {10.1073/pnas.1617948114},
   Key = {fds324102}
}

@article{fds329046,
   Author = {Golden, JS and Virdin, J and Nowacek, D and Halpin, P and Bennear, L and Patil, PG},
   Title = {Making sure the blue economy is green.},
   Journal = {Nature ecology & evolution},
   Volume = {1},
   Number = {2},
   Pages = {17},
   Year = {2017},
   Month = {January},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1038/s41559-016-0017},
   Doi = {10.1038/s41559-016-0017},
   Key = {fds329046}
}

@article{fds328661,
   Author = {Purcell, KM and Craig, JK and Nance, JM and Smith, MD and Bennear,
             LS},
   Title = {Fleet behavior is responsive to a large-scale environmental
             disturbance: Hypoxia effects on the spatial dynamics of the
             northern Gulf of Mexico shrimp fishery.},
   Journal = {PloS one},
   Volume = {12},
   Number = {8},
   Pages = {e0183032},
   Year = {2017},
   Month = {January},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0183032},
   Abstract = {The northwestern Gulf of Mexico shelf experiences one of the
             largest seasonal hypoxic zones in the western hemisphere.
             Hypoxia (dissolved oxygen, DO ≤ 2.0 mg·L-1) is most
             severe from May to August during the height of the Gulf
             shrimp fishery, but its effects on the fishery are not well
             known. Prior studies indicate that hypoxia alters the
             spatial dynamics of shrimp and other species through habitat
             loss and aggregation in nearby oxygenated refuge habitats.
             We hypothesized that hypoxia-induced changes in the
             distribution of shrimp also alter the spatial dynamics of
             the Gulf shrimp fleet. We integrated data on the geographic
             distribution of shrimp tows and bottom DO to evaluate the
             effects of hypoxia on spatial patterns in shrimping effort.
             Our analyses indicate that shrimping effort declines in low
             DO waters on both the Texas and Louisiana shelf, but that
             considerable effort still occurs in low DO waters off
             Louisiana, likely because riverine nutrients fuel both
             benthic production and low bottom DO in the same general
             regions. The response of the shrimp fleet to hypoxia on the
             Louisiana shelf was complex with shifts in effort inshore,
             offshore, westward, and eastward of the hypoxic zone, as
             well as to an oxygenated area between two hypoxia regimes
             associated with the Mississippi and the Atchafalaya River
             outflows. In contrast, effort on the Texas shelf mostly
             shifted offshore in response to low DO but also shifted
             inshore in some years. Spatial patterns in total shrimping
             effort were driven primarily by the number of shrimp tows,
             consistent with aggregation of the fleet outside of hypoxic
             waters, though tow duration also declined in low DO waters.
             Overall, our results demonstrate that hypoxia alters the
             spatial dynamics of the Gulf shrimp fishery with potential
             consequences for harvest interactions and the economic
             condition of the fishery.},
   Doi = {10.1371/journal.pone.0183032},
   Key = {fds328661}
}

@article{fds322571,
   Author = {Cunningham, S and Bennear, LS and Smith, MD},
   Title = {Spillovers in regional fisheries management: Do catch shares
             cause leakage?},
   Journal = {Land Economics},
   Volume = {92},
   Number = {2},
   Pages = {344-362},
   Publisher = {University of Wisconsin Press},
   Year = {2016},
   Month = {May},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.3368/le.92.2.344},
   Abstract = {Regional councils manage U.S. fisheries. Fishermen can
             participate in fisheries managed by multiple councils, and
             effort controls in one region could lead to effort leakage
             into another. Theoretical modeling demonstrates that
             positive, negative, and no leakage are possible. Using
             difference-in-differences, we test for leakage across
             regional boundaries for a catch share program in New England
             and find evidence that the New England groundfish sector
             program caused spillover into adjacent Mid-Atlantic
             fisheries. Aggregate Mid-Atlantic harvest volume increased
             among sector members after the policy change. We find
             leakage in individual fisheries with similar gear and high
             market substitutability with sector species.},
   Doi = {10.3368/le.92.2.344},
   Key = {fds322571}
}

@article{fds266085,
   Author = {Bennear, LS},
   Title = {Offshore oil and gas drilling: A review of regulatory
             regimes in the United States, United Kingdom, and
             Norway},
   Journal = {Review of Environmental Economics and Policy},
   Volume = {9},
   Number = {1},
   Pages = {2-22},
   Publisher = {Oxford University Press (OUP)},
   Year = {2015},
   Month = {January},
   ISSN = {1750-6816},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/reep/reu013},
   Doi = {10.1093/reep/reu013},
   Key = {fds266085}
}

@article{fds266088,
   Author = {Balasubramanya, S and Pfaff, A and Bennear, L and Tarozzi, A and Ahmed,
             KM and Schoenfeld, A and van Geen, A},
   Title = {Evolution of households' responses to the groundwater
             arsenic crisis in Bangladesh: information on environmental
             health risks can have increasing behavioral impact over
             time.},
   Journal = {Environment and development economics},
   Volume = {19},
   Number = {5},
   Pages = {631-647},
   Year = {2014},
   Month = {October},
   ISSN = {1355-770X},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/s1355770x13000612},
   Abstract = {A national campaign of well testing through 2003 enabled
             households in rural Bangladesh to switch, at least for
             drinking, from high-arsenic wells to neighboring
             lower-arsenic wells. We study the well-switching dynamics
             over time by re-interviewing, in 2008, a randomly selected
             subset of households in the Araihazar region who had been
             interviewed in 2005. Contrary to concerns that the impact of
             arsenic information on switching behavior would erode over
             time, we find that not only was 2003-2005 switching highly
             persistent but also new switching by 2008 doubled the share
             of households at unsafe wells who had switched. The passage
             of time also had a cost: 22% of households did not recall
             test results by 2008. The loss of arsenic knowledge led to
             staying at unsafe wells and switching from safe wells. Our
             results support ongoing well testing for arsenic to
             reinforce this beneficial information.},
   Doi = {10.1017/s1355770x13000612},
   Key = {fds266088}
}

@article{fds266086,
   Author = {Kirkpatrick, AJ and Bennear, LS},
   Title = {Promoting clean energy investment: An empirical analysis of
             property assessed clean energy},
   Journal = {Journal of Environmental Economics and Management},
   Volume = {68},
   Number = {2},
   Pages = {357-375},
   Publisher = {Elsevier BV},
   Year = {2014},
   Month = {September},
   ISSN = {0095-0696},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2014.05.001},
   Abstract = {From 2008 to 2010 a handful of Property-Assessed Clean
             Energy (PACE) programs offered property-secured loans to
             homeowners for residential clean energy investments. This
             analysis uses difference-in-differences models and synthetic
             counterfactual models to estimate the effect of three
             California PACE programs on residential photovoltaic
             installations. While PACE programs do not offer superior
             terms to other solar financing options, we find that PACE
             financing increases solar installations by approximately
             3.8. watts per owner-occupied household per quarter, a 108%
             increase over the mean watts per owner-occupied
             household.},
   Doi = {10.1016/j.jeem.2014.05.001},
   Key = {fds266086}
}

@article{fds266087,
   Author = {Smith, MD and Asche, F and Bennear, LS and Oglend,
             A},
   Title = {Spatial-dynamics of hypoxia and fisheries: The case of Gulf
             of Mexico brown shrimp},
   Journal = {Marine Resource Economics},
   Volume = {29},
   Number = {2},
   Pages = {111-131},
   Publisher = {University of Chicago Press},
   Year = {2014},
   Month = {May},
   ISSN = {0738-1360},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/676826},
   Abstract = {We analyze the Gulf of Mexico brown shrimp fishery and the
             potential impacts of a large seasonal area of hypoxia (low
             dissolved oxygen) that coincides with the peak shrimp
             season. A spatial-dynamic bioeconomic simulation embeds
             three biological impacts on shrimp: mortality, growth, and
             aggregation on hypoxic edges. Hypoxia creates feedbacks in
             the bioeconomic system, altering catch and effort patterns.
             System changes propagate over space to affect areas that do
             not experience hypoxia. Areas that might otherwise be
             considered controls in a natural experiments framework are
             contaminated by the ecological disturbance through spatial
             sorting. Aggregate predictions from simulations are similar
             to empirical fishery data. Average shrimp size and total
             landings are negatively correlated, as are hypoxic severity
             and landings. Shrimp size and hypoxic severity are only
             weakly negatively correlated. Growth overfishing, which
             varies with recruitment success and ecological disturbances,
             is a key mediating effect.},
   Doi = {10.1086/676826},
   Key = {fds266087}
}

@article{fds266089,
   Author = {Smith, MD and Asche, F and Bennear, LS and Havice, E and Read, AJ and Squires, D},
   Title = {Will a catch share for whales improve social
             welfare?},
   Journal = {Ecological applications : a publication of the Ecological
             Society of America},
   Volume = {24},
   Number = {1},
   Pages = {15-23},
   Year = {2014},
   Month = {January},
   ISSN = {1051-0761},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1890/13-0085.1},
   Abstract = {We critique a proposal to use catch shares to manage
             transboundary wildlife resources with potentially high
             non-extractive values, and we focus on the case of whales.
             Because whales are impure public goods, a policy that fails
             to capture all nonmarket benefits (due to free riding) could
             lead to a suboptimal outcome. Even if free riding were
             overcome, whale shares would face four implementation
             challenges. First, a whale share could legitimize the
             international trade in whale meat and expand the whale meat
             market. Second, a legal whale trade creates monitoring and
             enforcement challenges similar to those of organizations
             that manage highly migratory species such as tuna. Third, a
             whale share could create a new political economy of
             management that changes incentives and increases costs for
             nongovernmental organizations (NGOs) to achieve the current
             level of conservation. Fourth, a whale share program creates
             new logistical challenges for quota definition and
             allocation regardless of whether the market for whale
             products expands or contracts. Each of these issues, if left
             unaddressed, could result in lower overall welfare for
             society than under the status quo.},
   Doi = {10.1890/13-0085.1},
   Key = {fds266089}
}

@article{fds266097,
   Author = {Bennear, LS and Lee, JM and Taylor, LO},
   Title = {Municipal rebate programs for environmental retrofits: An
             evaluation of additionality and cost-effectiveness},
   Journal = {Journal of Policy Analysis and Management},
   Volume = {32},
   Number = {2},
   Pages = {350-372},
   Publisher = {WILEY},
   Year = {2013},
   Month = {March},
   ISSN = {0276-8739},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/pam.21692},
   Abstract = {When policies incentivize voluntary activities that also
             take place in the absence of the incentive, it is critical
             to identify the additionality of the policy-that is, the
             degree to which the policy results in actions that would not
             have occurred otherwise. Rebate programs have become a
             common conservation policy tool for local municipalities
             seeking to retrofit residential properties with efficient
             appliances. This research evaluates whether such rebates can
             be cost-effective means for water utilities to promote water
             conservation. A unique database is developed that combines
             water-use data over a three-year period for all households
             that participated in a utility's high-efficiency toilet
             (HET) rebate program, water-use data for a matched sample of
             neighbors who did not receive a rebate, and a survey of
             rebate participants. Difference-in-differences models
             indicate that installation of an HET reduces household water
             consumption by approximately 7 percent. While installation
             of an HET appears to be an effective means for achieving
             household reductions in water consumption, our results also
             suggest that the rebate program is a much less effective
             means for achieving household reductions in water
             consumption. Specifically, the rebate program is found to
             provide limited additional water savings beyond what would
             have occurred naturally and is responsible for only 37
             percent of the total water reduction attributable to the
             installation of HETs over the study period. © 2013 by the
             Association for Public Policy Analysis and
             Management.},
   Doi = {10.1002/pam.21692},
   Key = {fds266097}
}

@article{fds214784,
   Author = {Asche, Frank and Lori S. Bennear and Atle Oglend and Martin D.
             Smith},
   Title = {U.S. Shrimp Market Integration},
   Journal = {Marine Resources Economics},
   Volume = {29},
   Number = {2},
   Pages = {181-192},
   Year = {2012},
   Key = {fds214784}
}

@article{fds266101,
   Author = {Asche, F and Bennear, LS and Oglend, A and Smith,
             MD},
   Title = {U.S. Shrimp Market Integration},
   Journal = {Marine Resource Economics},
   Volume = {27},
   Number = {2},
   Pages = {181-192},
   Publisher = {University of Chicago Press},
   Year = {2012},
   ISSN = {0738-1360},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.5950/0738-1360-27.2.181},
   Abstract = {Recent supply shocks in the Gulf of Mexico-including
             hurricanes, the Deepwater Horizon oil spill, and the
             seasonal appearance of a large dead zone of low oxygen water
             (hypoxia)-have raised concerns about the economic viability
             of the U.S. shrimp fishery. The ability of U.S. shrimpers to
             mediate supply shocks through increased prices hinges on the
             degree of market integration, both among shrimp of different
             sizes classes and between U.S. wild caught shrimp and
             imported farmed shrimp. We use detailed data on shrimp
             prices by size class and import prices to conduct a
             co-integration analysis of market integration in the shrimp
             industry. We find significant evidence of market
             integration, suggesting that the law of one price holds for
             this industry. Hence, in the face of a supply shocks, prices
             do not rise; instead, imports of foreign farmed fish
             increase.},
   Doi = {10.5950/0738-1360-27.2.181},
   Key = {fds266101}
}

@article{fds328354,
   Author = {Bennear, L and Tarozzi, A and Pfaff, A and Balasubramanya, S and Ahmed,
             KM and Geen, AV},
   Title = {Impact of a randomized controlled trial in arsenic risk
             communication on household water-source choices in
             Bangladesh},
   Journal = {Journal of Environmental Economics and Management},
   Volume = {65},
   Number = {2},
   Pages = {225-240},
   Year = {2012},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2012.07.006},
   Abstract = {We conducted a randomized controlled trial in rural
             Bangladesh to examine how household drinking-water choices
             were affected by two different messages about risk from
             naturally occurring groundwater arsenic. Households in both
             randomized treatment arms were informed about the arsenic
             level in their well and whether that level was above or
             below the Bangladesh standard for arsenic. Households in one
             group of villages were encouraged to seek water from wells
             below the national standard. Households in the second group
             of villages received additional information explaining that
             lower-arsenic well water is always safer and these
             households were encouraged to seek water from wells with
             lower levels of arsenic, irrespective of the national
             standard. A simple model of household drinking-water choice
             indicates that the effect of the emphasis message is
             theoretically ambiguous. Empirically, we find that the
             richer message had a negative, but insignificant, effect on
             well-switching rates, but the estimates are sufficiently
             precise that we can rule out large positive effects. The
             main policy implication of this finding is that a one-time
             oral message conveying richer information on arsenic risks,
             while inexpensive and easily scalable, is unlikely to be
             successful in reducing exposure relative to the status-quo
             policy. © 2012 Elsevier Inc. All rights
             reserved.},
   Doi = {10.1016/j.jeem.2012.07.006},
   Key = {fds328354}
}

@article{fds328662,
   Author = {Bennear, LS and Taylor, L and Lee, J},
   Title = {Participation Incentives, Rebound Effects and the
             Cost-Effectiveness of Rebates for Water-Efficient
             Appliances},
   Journal = {Duke Environmental Economics Working Paper},
   Number = {11},
   Year = {2011},
   Month = {November},
   Key = {fds328662}
}

@article{fds328355,
   Author = {Tarozzi, A and Bennear, LS and Pfaff, A and Soumya, HB and Ahmed, KM and van Geen, A},
   Title = {Bright Lines, Risk Beliefs, and Risk Avoidance: Evidence
             from a Randomized Intervention in Bangladesh},
   Journal = {Economic Research Initiatives at Duke Working
             Paper},
   Number = {77},
   Year = {2011},
   Month = {July},
   Key = {fds328355}
}

@article{fds328356,
   Author = {Bennear, LS and Tarozzi, A and Pfaff, A and Soumya, HB and Ahmed, KM and van Geen, A},
   Title = {Bright Lines, Risk Beliefs, and Risk Avoidance: Evidence
             from a Randomized Intervention in Bangladesh},
   Year = {2010},
   Month = {October},
   Key = {fds328356}
}

@article{fds266103,
   Author = {Bennear, LS and Olmstead, SM},
   Title = {Information Disclosure and Drinking Water
             Quality},
   Journal = {Resources Magazine},
   Pages = {88-89},
   Publisher = {Routledge},
   Year = {2009},
   Month = {Fall},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.4324/9781936331253},
   Doi = {10.4324/9781936331253},
   Key = {fds266103}
}

@article{fds266109,
   Author = {Bennear, LS and Jessoe, KK and Olmstead, SM},
   Title = {Sampling out: regulatory avoidance and the Total Coliform
             Rule.},
   Journal = {Environmental science & technology},
   Volume = {43},
   Number = {14},
   Pages = {5176-5182},
   Year = {2009},
   Month = {July},
   ISSN = {0013-936X},
   url = {http://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pubmed/19708338},
   Abstract = {This paper investigates strategic noncompliance with the
             Total Coliform Rule (TCR) under the U.S. Safe Drinking Water
             Act. The structure of the TCR provides incentives for some
             piped drinking water systems to avoid violations by taking
             additional water quality samples. We estimate the prevalence
             of this behavior and its potential impact on violations
             using monthly data for more than 500 Massachusetts water
             systems, 1993-2003. We find evidence that strategic
             oversampling is occurring. Water systems most likely to
             avoid violations by oversampling are most likely to
             oversample. A significant number of additional violations
             would have occurred if systems had adhered to legal sampling
             requirements, rather than oversampling. Our analysis of
             potential impacts of regulatory avoidance under the current
             rule suggests that alternative policies for monitoring
             bacteria in drinking water should be considered.},
   Doi = {10.1021/es803115k},
   Key = {fds266109}
}

@article{fds168621,
   Author = {L.S. Bennear and K.K. Jessoe and S.M. Olmstead},
   Title = {Sampling Out: Regulatory Avoidance and the Total Coliform
             Rule},
   Journal = {Environ Sci & Technol},
   Year = {2009},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1021/es803115k},
   Key = {fds168621}
}

@article{fds266102,
   Author = {Bennear, LS},
   Title = {What do we really know? The effect of reporting thresholds
             on inferences using environmental right‐to‐know
             data},
   Journal = {Regulation & Governance},
   Volume = {2},
   Number = {3},
   Pages = {293-315},
   Publisher = {Wiley},
   Year = {2008},
   Month = {September},
   ISSN = {1748-5983},
   url = {http://gateway.webofknowledge.com/gateway/Gateway.cgi?GWVersion=2&SrcApp=PARTNER_APP&SrcAuth=LinksAMR&KeyUT=WOS:000259322500002&DestLinkType=FullRecord&DestApp=ALL_WOS&UsrCustomerID=47d3190e77e5a3a53558812f597b0b92},
   Abstract = {<jats:title>Abstract</jats:title><jats:p>Environmental
             right‐to‐know regulations require regulated entities to
             publicly disclose measures of environmental performance but
             exempt entities from these disclosure requirements if they
             manufacture, process, or use a chemical below some threshold
             level. Environmental right‐to‐know data are widely used
             to assess environmental performance by academics,
             regulators, non‐profit organizations, and the public. This
             paper uses data from Massachusetts to estimate the effect of
             reporting thresholds in environmental right‐to‐know
             programs on the validity of inferences using data from these
             programs. The analysis indicates that errors in inference
             introduced by reporting thresholds may be significant. Up to
             40% of the observed decline in reported toxic releases in
             Massachusetts may be attributed to non‐reporting due to
             the reporting thresholds. In addition, quartile rankings of
             facilities may be in error up to 45% of the time when
             behavior around the reporting thresholds is not taken into
             account.</jats:p>},
   Doi = {10.1111/j.1748-5991.2008.00042.x},
   Key = {fds266102}
}

@article{fds266104,
   Author = {Bennear, LS and Olmstead, SM},
   Title = {The impacts of the "right to know": Information disclosure
             and the violation of drinking water standards},
   Journal = {Journal of Environmental Economics and Management},
   Volume = {56},
   Number = {2},
   Pages = {117-130},
   Publisher = {Elsevier BV},
   Year = {2008},
   Month = {January},
   ISSN = {0095-0696},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2008.03.002},
   Abstract = {Information disclosure regulations are increasingly common,
             but their effects on the behavior of regulated firms are
             unclear. The 1996 Amendments to the Safe Drinking Water Act
             mandated that community drinking water suppliers issue to
             customers annual consumer confidence reports (CCRs),
             containing information on violations of drinking water
             regulations and on observed contaminant levels. We examine
             the impact of mandatory information provision on drinking
             water violations by 517 community water systems in the
             Commonwealth of Massachusetts from 1990 to 2003. Results
             suggest that larger utilities required to mail CCRs directly
             to customers reduced total violations by between 30% and 44%
             as a result of this policy, and reduced the more severe
             health violations by 40-57%. © 2008 Elsevier Inc. All
             rights reserved.},
   Doi = {10.1016/j.jeem.2008.03.002},
   Key = {fds266104}
}

@article{fds266108,
   Author = {Bennear, LS and Stavins, RN},
   Title = {Second-best theory and the use of multiple policy
             instruments},
   Journal = {Environmental and Resource Economics},
   Volume = {37},
   Number = {1},
   Pages = {111-129},
   Publisher = {Springer Nature},
   Year = {2007},
   Month = {May},
   ISSN = {0924-6460},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10640-007-9110-y},
   Abstract = {In many cases policy makers employ multiple instruments to
             address a single environmental problem, but much of the
             economics literature on instrument choice focuses on
             comparing properties of single policy instruments. We argue
             that under a fairly broad set of circumstances the use of
             multiple policy instruments can be justified as optimal in a
             second-best world. We examine two broad categories of
             second-best policy making: cases with multiple market
             failures only some of which can be corrected at any one
             time; and cases with exogenous (often political) constraints
             that cannot be removed. The fact that the use of multiple
             policy instruments can be justified economically in these
             two cases does not imply, however, that all multiple
             instruments employed in actual practice are economically
             justified. © 2007 Springer Science+Business Media,
             Inc.},
   Doi = {10.1007/s10640-007-9110-y},
   Key = {fds266108}
}

@article{fds266100,
   Author = {Bennear, LS},
   Title = {Are Management-Based Regulations Effective?},
   Journal = {Journal of Policy Analysis and Management},
   Volume = {26},
   Number = {2},
   Pages = {327-348},
   Publisher = {WILEY},
   Year = {2007},
   ISSN = {0276-8739},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/pam.20250},
   Abstract = {This paper evaluates a recent innovation in regulating risk
             called management-based regulation. Traditionally, risk
             regulation has either specified a particular means of
             achieving a risk-reduction goal or specified the goal and
             left the means of achieving that goal up to the regulated
             entity. In contrast, management-based regulation neither
             explicitly imposes the means, nor the ends. Rather, what is
             required is that each regulated entity review its production
             processes and develop a set of goals and procedures that
             will reduce risk. I evaluate the effectiveness of
             management-based regulation by taking advantage of policy
             variation that occurred when 14 states adopted such
             regulations for toxic chemical control in the 1990s. Using
             panel data for just over 31,000 manufacturing plants in the
             United States, I investigate whether facilities subject to
             management-based regulations had larger changes in total
             quantities of toxic chemical releases, engaged in more
             pollution prevention activities, or reported fewer toxic
             chemicals to the Toxics Release Inventory (TRI). The results
             indicate that management-based regulation has had a
             measurable positive effect on the environmental performance
             of manufacturing plants. In particular, plants subject to
             management-based regulation experienced larger decreases in
             total pounds of toxic chemicals released and were more
             likely to engage in source reduction activities. © 2007 by
             the Association for Public Policy Analysis and
             Management.},
   Doi = {10.1002/pam.20250},
   Key = {fds266100}
}

@article{fds266099,
   Author = {Bennear, LS and Stavins, RN and Wagner, AF},
   Title = {Using revealed preferences to infer environmental benefits:
             Evidence from recreational fishing licenses},
   Journal = {Journal of Regulatory Economics},
   Volume = {28},
   Number = {2},
   Pages = {157-179},
   Publisher = {Springer Nature},
   Year = {2005},
   Month = {September},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s11149-005-3107-7},
   Abstract = {We develop and apply a new method for estimating the
             economic benefits of an environmental amenity. The method is
             based upon the notion of estimating the derived demand for a
             privately traded option to utilize an open access good. In
             particular, the demand for state fishing licenses is used to
             infer the benefits of recreational fishing. Using panel data
             on state fishing license sales and prices for the
             continental United States over a 15-year period, combined
             with data on substitute prices and demographic variables, a
             license demand function is estimated with instrumental
             variable procedures to allow for the potential endogeneity
             of administered prices. The econometric results lead to
             estimates of the benefits of a fishing license, and
             subsequently to the expected benefits of a recreational
             fishing day. In contrast with previous studies, which have
             utilized travel cost or hypothetical market methods, our
             approach provides estimates that are directly comparable
             across geographic areas. Our findings show substantial
             variation in the value of a recreational fishing day across
             geographic areas in the United States. This suggests that
             current practice of using benefits estimates from one part
             of the country in national or regional analyses may lead to
             substantial bias in benefits estimates. © 2005 Springer
             Science+Business Media, Inc.},
   Doi = {10.1007/s11149-005-3107-7},
   Key = {fds266099}
}

@article{fds328663,
   Author = {Bennear, LS},
   Title = {Strategic Response to Regulatory Thresholds: Evidence from
             the Massachusetts Toxics Use Reduction Act},
   Year = {2005},
   Month = {June},
   Key = {fds328663}
}

@article{fds266105,
   Author = {Bennear, LS and Coglianese, C},
   Title = {Measuring progress: Program evaluaton of environmental
             policies},
   Journal = {Environment},
   Volume = {47},
   Number = {2},
   Pages = {22-39},
   Publisher = {Informa UK Limited},
   Year = {2005},
   Month = {March},
   ISSN = {0013-9157},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.3200/ENVT.47.2.22-39},
   Doi = {10.3200/ENVT.47.2.22-39},
   Key = {fds266105}
}

@article{fds328664,
   Author = {Bennear, LS and Stavins, RN and Wagner, A},
   Title = {Private Options to Use Public Goods: Using Revealed
             Preferences to Estimate Environmental Benefits},
   Journal = {Journal of Regulatory Economics},
   Volume = {28},
   Number = {2},
   Pages = {157-180},
   Year = {2005},
   Key = {fds328664}
}

@article{fds266107,
   Author = {Snyder, LD and Miller, NH and Stavins, RN},
   Title = {The effects of environmental regulation on technology
             diffusion: The case of chlorine manufacturing},
   Journal = {American Economic Review},
   Volume = {93},
   Number = {2},
   Pages = {431-435},
   Publisher = {American Economic Association},
   Year = {2003},
   Month = {May},
   ISSN = {0002-8282},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/000282803321947470},
   Doi = {10.1257/000282803321947470},
   Key = {fds266107}
}

@article{fds266106,
   Author = {Sadd, JL and Pastor, M and Boer, JT and Snyder, LD},
   Title = {"Every breath you take ... ": The demographics of toxic air
             releases in Southern California},
   Journal = {Economic Development Quarterly},
   Volume = {13},
   Number = {2},
   Pages = {107-123},
   Publisher = {SAGE Publications},
   Year = {1999},
   Month = {January},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/089124249901300201},
   Abstract = {In this article, the authors investigate the relationship
             between ethnicity and potential environmental hazards in the
             metropolitan Los Angeles area. Using a variety of
             techniques, including geographic information systems (GIS)
             mapping, univariate comparisons, and logit, ordered logit,
             and tobit regression analysis, the authors find that, even
             controlling for other factors such as income and the extent
             of manufacturing employment and land use, minority residents
             tend to be disproportionately located in neighborhoods
             surrounding toxic air emissions. The results generally
             support the propositions of the proponents of "environmental
             justice "; in the conclusion, they consider what this might
             mean for urban land use and environmental
             policy.},
   Doi = {10.1177/089124249901300201},
   Key = {fds266106}
}

@article{fds266098,
   Author = {Boer, JT and Pastor, M and Sadd, JL and Snyder, LD},
   Title = {Is there environmental racism? The demographics of hazardous
             waste in Los Angeles County},
   Journal = {Social Science Quarterly},
   Volume = {78},
   Number = {4},
   Pages = {X-810},
   Year = {1997},
   Month = {December},
   Abstract = {Objective. The "environmental justice" movement has
             suggested that demographic inequities characterize the
             location of hazardous waste treatment, storage, and disposal
             facilities (TSDFs). While some researchers have found
             evidence that TSDFs are disproportionately located in
             minority areas, others attribute TSDF location to nonracial
             factors such as income and industrial employment. Methods.
             We used both univariate and multivariate techniques to
             analyze the location of TSDFs in Los Angeles County,
             California; the focus on one county allowed us to overcome
             the problem of "false" addresses for TSDF sites and to
             introduce specific land use/zoning variables that are not
             used in the other studies. Results. In our univariate
             results and the multivariate model, we find that (1)
             industrial land use and manufacturing employment do matter,
             as suggested by critics of environmental justice; (2) income
             has first a positive, then a negative effect on TSDF
             location, a pattern that likely reflects the fact that the
             poorest communities have little economic activity while
             wealthier communities have the economic and political power
             to resist negative environmental externalities; and (3) race
             and ethnicity are still significantly associated with TSDF
             location, even when percentage African American and
             percentage Latino are evaluated as separate groupings. Taken
             together, the results suggest that communities most affected
             by TSDFs in the Los Angeles area are working-class
             communities of color located near industrial
             areas.},
   Key = {fds266098}
}

@article{fds328665,
   Author = {Boer, LSBWT and Sadd, J and Pastor, M},
   Title = {Is There Environmental Racism: An Empirical Analysis of the
             Geographical Distribution of Hazardous Waste Facilities in
             Los Angeles County},
   Journal = {Social Science Quarterly},
   Year = {1997},
   Month = {December},
   Key = {fds328665}
}


%% Papers Accepted   
@article{fds214785,
   Author = {Bennear, Lori S. and Alessandro Tarozzi  and Alexander Pfaff and Soumya H. Balasubramanya and Kazi Matin Ahmed and Alexander
             van Geen},
   Title = {Impacts of a Randomized Controlled Trial in Arsenic Risk
             Communication on Household Water-Source Choices in
             Bangladesh},
   Journal = {Journal of Environmental Economics and Management},
   Year = {2012},
   Key = {fds214785}
}

@article{fds214786,
   Author = {Bennear, Lori S. and Jonathan M. Lee and Laura O.
             Taylor},
   Title = {Municipal Rebate Programs for Environmental Retrofits: An
             Evaluation of Additionality and Cost-Effectiveness},
   Journal = {Journal of Policy Analysis and Management},
   Year = {2012},
   Key = {fds214786}
}


%% Book Chapters   
@misc{fds335822,
   Author = {Balleisen, EJ and Bennear, LS and Krawiec, KD and Wiener,
             JB},
   Title = {Recalibrating risk: Crises, learning, and regulatory
             change},
   Pages = {540-561},
   Booktitle = {Policy Shock: Recalibrating Risk and Regulation after Oil
             Spills, Nuclear Accidents and Financial Crises},
   Publisher = {Cambridge University Press},
   Year = {2017},
   Month = {January},
   ISBN = {9781107140219},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/9781316492635.018},
   Abstract = {It is often observed that crisis events spur new regulation.
             An extensive literature focuses on the role of disasters,
             tragedies, scandals, shocks, and other untoward events in
             stimulating regulatory responses (Baumgartner and Jones
             1993; Percival 1998; Kuran and Sunstein 1999; Birkland 2006;
             Repetto 2006; Wiener and Richman 2010; Wuthnow 2010). We
             have highlighted numerous examples of arguably crisis-driven
             regulation in the introductory chapter (Balleisen et al.,
             this volume) and in the several case study chapters in this
             book. The notion that crises spur regulation has become a
             “commonplace assertion,” and yet one that is “so
             widely held … that it remains virtually unexamined in
             empirical and historical analyses” (Carpenter and Sin
             2007, 149). Observing this relationship does not itself
             explain what causal mechanisms may be driving it (Carpenter
             and Sin 2007, 154). And the relationship does not always
             hold (Kahn 2007). We do not claim that all crises spur
             regulatory change, nor that all regulatory changes arise
             from crises. Some crisis events do not produce significant
             regulatory change – perhaps including mass shootings in
             the United States, and Hurricanes Katrina and Sandy. Some
             regulatory changes occur without preceding crisis events –
             such as the Acid Rain Program of the 1990 Clean Air Act.
             This volume has sought to enrich the empirical understanding
             of how the process of crisis stimulus and regulatory
             response unfolds. Our main question has been not whether,
             but rather how, regulatory systems change in response to
             crises. Going beyond the generic assertion that crises spur
             regulation, we have explored diverse ways in which
             regulatory change may play out: how different types of
             regulatory responses may follow from different kinds of
             crises. In this volume, we have studied a set of cases in
             which some regulatory change typically did follow a crisis
             event, in order to understand how that process led to
             different types of regulatory changes in different contexts.
             The case studies in this volume – focusing on oil spills,
             nuclear power accidents, and financial crashes, with
             regulatory responses in the United States, Europe, and Japan
             – illustrate a wide array of crises, institutions, actors,
             countries, time periods, and policy changes.},
   Doi = {10.1017/9781316492635.018},
   Key = {fds335822}
}

@misc{fds335823,
   Author = {Balleisen, EJ and Bennear, LS and Krawiec, KD and Wiener,
             JB},
   Title = {Introduction},
   Pages = {1-40},
   Booktitle = {Policy Shock: Recalibrating Risk and Regulation after Oil
             Spills, Nuclear Accidents and Financial Crises},
   Publisher = {Cambridge University Press},
   Year = {2017},
   Month = {January},
   ISBN = {9781107140219},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/9781316492635.001},
   Abstract = {Crises punctuate our world. Their causes and consequences
             are woven through complex, interconnected social and
             technological systems. Consider these three recent events,
             each of which dramatically upended expectations about risk:
             • In the fall of 2008, the global financial system
             experienced a full-blown panic. Credit flows seized up,
             ushering in the worst global recession since the 1930s and
             leading newspapers to convey the resulting “shocks” to
             financial markets. • In April 2010, a blowout at the
             British Petroleum Deepwater Horizon drilling platform killed
             eleven workers and triggered a three-month-long oil spill,
             sending nearly five million barrels of crude into the
             Northern Gulf of Mexico, which fouled beaches, estuaries,
             and fishing grounds. • In March 2011, an earthquake and a
             resulting tsunami killed 20,000 people in Japan. The natural
             disaster also caused reactor meltdowns at the Fukushima
             nuclear power plant, forcing the evacuation of tens of
             thousands of people, unleashing a long-term leak of
             radioactive water into the Pacific Ocean and creating a
             daunting set of challenges as officials sought to stabilize
             pools of spent fuel rods and protect local populations from
             radioactive fallout. Each of these three recent events
             attracted extraordinary attention from the media and the
             global public, raising concerns about dangers that may lurk
             within the complex technological and social systems on which
             we depend to sustain our economy and way of life. They also
             generated criticisms of the regulatory systems that were
             supposed to prevent such failures, as well as demands for
             new regulatory actions to reduce the risks that the crises
             had brought into sharp relief. In the aftermath, policy
             elites and the broader public ponder the meaning of such
             events and look for appropriate responses. Once a consensus
             emerges that they indeed constitute crises (and sometimes
             even before), government agencies, legislative committees,
             think tanks, citizens’ groups, scholars, and often
             official commissions begin to investigate their causes,
             consider whether better policy might have prevented them,
             and debate what regulatory adjustments governments should
             adopt, if any.},
   Doi = {10.1017/9781316492635.001},
   Key = {fds335823}
}

@misc{fds335824,
   Author = {Bennear, LS},
   Title = {Economic analysis, risk regulation, and the dynamics of
             policy regret},
   Pages = {43-57},
   Booktitle = {Policy Shock: Recalibrating Risk and Regulation after Oil
             Spills, Nuclear Accidents and Financial Crises},
   Publisher = {Cambridge University Press},
   Year = {2017},
   Month = {January},
   ISBN = {9781107140219},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/9781316492635.002},
   Abstract = {In the wake of a crisis, a common refrain is “Why didn't
             we do more to prevent this terrible disaster?” All too
             frequently, ex-post analysis suggests that policy did not
             sufficiently account for extreme events, or that the level
             of regulation imposed or enforced was insufficient. For
             example, after Hurricane Katrina a bipartisan commission
             found that the levee system had been designed for
             “standard” hurricanes and not for the most severe storms
             (US House of Representatives 2006). The bipartisan
             commission investigating the Deepwater Horizon oil spill
             found that inspections and regulations were insufficient to
             prevent an oil spill of that significant magnitude (National
             Commission 2011). Similarly, the Financial Crisis Inquiry
             Commission found that “widespread failures in financial
             regulation and supervision proved devastating to the
             stability of the nation's financial markets” (Financial
             Crisis Inquiry Commission 2011). For the sake of simplicity,
             I will refer to this phenomenon as “policy regret.”
             Policy regret is characterized by a post-crisis sentiment
             that decision-makers had not sufficiently identified the
             probability or seriousness of risks before the onset of
             crisis and so had insufficiently acted to prevent it. This
             sentiment tends to be strongly correlated with an impulse to
             engage in significant post-crisis policy reforms. One of the
             key features of policy regret seems to be the belief,
             ex-post, that the problems with the current regulations
             should have been known and corrected in advance. This
             characteristic implies systematic failures in the regulatory
             process that hinder implementation of programs and policies
             that would actually have been welfare enhancing. The focus
             of this chapter is on the role of economic analysis in the
             regulatory process and what role, if any, these analyses
             play in reducing or fostering policy regret. Economic
             analyses of risk regulations of some form have been required
             since the Nixon administration (Copeland 2011). However,
             most people associate requirements for economic analysis,
             and particularly benefit-cost analysis, with Executive Order
             12291 issued in 1981 by President Ronald Reagan. This
             executive order required benefit-cost analysis for all
             regulations with an annual cost of $100 million or more
             (Copeland 2011). More specifically, it required agencies to
             monetize all benefits and costs and to choose both
             regulatory objectives and regulatory alternatives (levels)
             that maximized net benefits to society. This executive order
             was maintained by President George H.W. Bush and was
             replaced by a similar executive order (EO 12866) by
             President Bill Clinton.},
   Doi = {10.1017/9781316492635.002},
   Key = {fds335824}
}

@misc{fds341094,
   Author = {Balleisen, EJ and Bennear, L and Cheang, D and Free, J and Hayes, M and Pechar, E and Preston, AC},
   Title = {Institutional Mechanisms for Investigating the Regulatory
             Implications of a Major Crisis: The Commission of Inquiry
             and the Safety Board},
   Pages = {485-539},
   Booktitle = {Policy Shock: Regulatory Responses to Nuclear Accidents,
             Offshore Oil Spill, and Financial Crises},
   Publisher = {Cambridge University Press},
   Year = {2017},
   Month = {January},
   ISBN = {9781107140219},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/9781316492635.017},
   Abstract = {As we have seen, events like the 2008 financial crash, the
             BP- Deepwater Horizon Gulf oil spill, or the Fukushima
             nuclear accident trigger massive public attention and often
             significant regulatory reactions. Once media coverage and
             the crystallization of public opinion anoint such events as
             crises that require priority consideration, policy-makers
             have to discern a way forward. This process typically
             involves some effort to investigate the recent events and
             identify their causes. The bodies responsible for such
             retrospective analysis usually look ahead as well as back.
             They make judgments about whether policy-makers should
             revise their risk assessments in light of events,
             recalibrate their views of trade-offs among competing policy
             goals, and reconstruct strategies of risk management. There
             are many ways to structure investigation into the causes and
             policy implications of crisis events. In some cases,
             governments rely on the standard institutions of
             policy-making. Investigatory bodies at every level of
             government pride themselves in their ability to perform
             probing, incisive studies that reveal pivotal evidence and
             offer relevant analysis for the formulation of policy
             recommendations. The applicable legislative committees ask
             staff to undertake extensive background studies and hold a
             series of hearings in the usual course of business. They
             then publish extensive reports to guide and justify
             legislature reforms, or legislative inaction. Executive
             agencies responsible for mitigating or preventing relevant
             risks may pursue similar inquiries, whether based on staff
             research or the work of outside experts, and either alone or
             through the auspices of cross-agency task forces. The
             “normal” channels of policy assessment, however, have
             limitations. They sometimes lack expertise with regard to
             the issues at hand, and inevitably take place in a context
             of partisan politics. They also place the responsibility for
             policy analysis in the hands of the very institutions whose
             prior choices failed to prevent the crisis event. Officials
             within those institutions have strong incentives to shape
             explanatory narratives so as to deflect blame for the events
             that have brought such significant social and economic
             costs. These shortcomings have frequently led governments to
             shy away from the typical institutional channels of
             democratic governance as the most appropriate policy
             coroners to undertake a crisis event “autopsy.” On many
             occasions, governments have instead turned to ostensibly
             more independent mechanisms of investigation and policy
             analysis.},
   Doi = {10.1017/9781316492635.017},
   Key = {fds341094}
}

@misc{fds266095,
   Author = {Bennear, LS and Coglianese, C},
   Title = {Flexible Environmental Regulation},
   Pages = {582-604},
   Booktitle = {The Oxford Handbook of U.S. Environmental
             Policy},
   Publisher = {Oxford University Press},
   Editor = {Kamieniecki, S and Kraft, M},
   Year = {2012},
   Month = {November},
   ISBN = {9780199744671},
   Abstract = {“Flexible regulation” might sound like an oxymoron but
             it has become a widely accepted catch phrase for pragmatic
             regulation that promises the achievement of important public
             policy objectives at low cost. Given the growing interest in
             flexible regulation in recent decades, we consider in this
             paper what can be learned from the U.S. experience with
             flexible environmental regulation. We consider four types of
             flexible regulation: (1) flexible commands, such as
             performance standards, information disclosure rules, and
             management-based regulations; (2) flexible targets, such as
             offsets, bubbles, and trading; (3) flexible consequences,
             such as voluntary programs and agreements; and (4) flexible
             regulators, such as systems of self-regulation and
             self-policing. Researchers have demonstrated that many
             flexible approaches can sometimes work, to some degree, but
             just as flexible policies can vary in form, we find that
             they also vary in results. What remains, we argue, is to
             determine whether the marginal, and at times only potential,
             gains from flexible forms of regulation are enough to
             justify their increased use.},
   Key = {fds266095}
}

@misc{fds266094,
   Author = {Bennear, LS},
   Title = {Beyond Belts and Suspenders: Promoting Private Risk
             Management in Offshore Drilling},
   Volume = {9780812207491},
   Pages = {49-67},
   Booktitle = {Regulatory Breakdown? The Crisis of Confidence in U.S.
             Regulation},
   Publisher = {University of Pennsylvania Press},
   Editor = {Coglianese, C},
   Year = {2012},
   ISBN = {978-0-8122-4460-1},
   Abstract = {On April 20, 2010, eleven workers were killed in an
             explosion on the Deepwater Horizon rig in the pro cess of
             drilling the Macondo well off the Gulf of Mexico. The
             blowout resulted in between four and five million barrels of
             oil leaking into the Gulf of Mexico. Early estimates of the
             damages from the oil spill are in the range of $20 billion
             with an additional $17 billion in fines (Economist 2010).
             There are many entities at blame for the significant human
             and environmental disaster in the Gulf, and regulators have
             not escaped unscathed. Regulators at the Minerals Management
             Ser vice (MMS), the federal agency charged with issuing
             permits and overseeing safety of offshore oil drilling,
             appeared compromised by conflicts of interest and
             unqualified to ensure safety in operations (CNN 2010;
             Leonnig 2010; U.S. Department of the Interior 2010). The
             magnitude of the damages from the Gulf oil spill, combined
             with perceptions of regulatory capture at MMS, has brought
             into question the sufficiency of current regulatory
             approaches to offshore oil drilling. Prior to the Gulf oil
             spill, the primary form of regulation that applied to
             offshore oil drilling was a set of highly prescriptive
             command-andcontrol regulations requiring significant
             redundancy in safety systems, an approach I call "belts and
             suspenders." The belts-and-suspenders regulations were
             coupled with a strict liability regime where the operating
             company-BP in this case-was strictly liable for damages up
             to $75 million, with additional damages covered by a
             government pool of funds generated through taxes on oil
             (Hargreaves 2010). Arguably, this coupling of regulatory
             systems should have created the correct incentives for
             companies to manage risks. The required safety technologies
             should have been in place and, given the financial liability
             for damages, BP and its contractors should have had the
             incentives to ensure that all these systems were working
             properly. Nonetheless, a disaster occurred. To advance the
             search for better ways to prevent such disasters in the
             future, I analyze in this chapter three ways of regulating
             offshore drilling in the United States. The first approach
             is the belts-and-suspenders approach used both prior to and
             in response to the Gulf oil spill. I argue that the
             belts-and-suspenders approach is flawed because it fails to
             account for the inherent risk derived from drilling
             technologies' dependence on human control. The
             belts-and-suspenders approach may even encourage greater
             risk taking by human operators because it creates the
             impression that multiple safety systems will catch any
             errors before a significant accident occurs. The second
             approach is management-based regulation, which requires
             drilling operators to develop detailed safety and risk
             management plans. This approach has been used to regulate
             offshore drilling in other countries and has been adopted by
             the United States as a supplemental response to the Gulf oil
             spill. I consider the suitability and likely effectiveness
             of management-based regulation for regulating offshore
             drilling, concluding that such an approach by itself does
             little to ensure that risk management plans are fully
             implemented. The third approach would be to apply a
             deposit-discount-refund system, which would require an
             up-front establishment of a project-level "safety deposit."
             Operators can earn "discounts" on the size of their safety
             deposit by earning high grades on in de pen dent third-party
             assessments of their safety management plans. And upon
             successful completion of the project, the safety deposit is
             refunded to the company. In this way, the
             deposit-discount-refund system provides an incentive for
             companies to carry out effective risk management
             practices.},
   Key = {fds266094}
}

@misc{fds266091,
   Author = {Bennear, LS and Olmstead, SM},
   Title = {Information Disclosure and Drinking Water
             Quality},
   Pages = {122-123},
   Booktitle = {Issues of the Day: 100 Commentaries on Climate, Energy, the
             Environment, Transportation, and Public Health
             Policy},
   Publisher = {Resources for the Future Press},
   Year = {2010},
   Key = {fds266091}
}

@misc{fds266093,
   Author = {Bennear, LS},
   Title = {Evaluating Management-Based Regulation: A Valuable Tool in
             the Regulatory Tool Box?},
   Pages = {51-86},
   Booktitle = {Leveraging the Private Sector: Management-Based Strategies
             for Improving Environmental Performance},
   Publisher = {Resources for the Future Press},
   Editor = {Coglianese, C and Nash, J},
   Year = {2006},
   ISBN = {9781936331444},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.4324/9781936331444},
   Doi = {10.4324/9781936331444},
   Key = {fds266093}
}

@misc{fds266092,
   Author = {Bennear, LS and Coglianese, C},
   Title = {Program Evaluation of Environmental Policies: Toward
             Evidence-Based Decision Making},
   Booktitle = {Decision Making for the Environment: Social and Behavioral
             Science Research Priorities},
   Publisher = {National Academies Press},
   Address = {Washington, DC},
   Editor = {Brewer, GD and Stern, PC},
   Year = {2005},
   Key = {fds266092}
}


%% Chapters in Books   
@misc{fds266090,
   Author = {Bennear, LS and Dickenson, KL},
   Title = {Incorporating Evaluation in the Regulatory
             Process”},
   Year = {2011},
   Key = {fds266090}
}

@misc{fds343268,
   Author = {Bennear, LS and Coglianese, C},
   Title = {Evaluating Environmental Policies},
   Pages = {22-22},
   Year = {2004},
   Month = {November},
   Key = {fds343268}
}


%% Op-eds   
@misc{fds304038,
   Author = {Bennear, LS and Smith, MD},
   Title = {Success or Selection: An Economic Perspective on Fisheries
             Co-Management},
   Journal = {Working Papers on the Web},
   Year = {2011},
   Month = {April},
   Key = {fds304038}
}


%% Working Papers   
@article{fds154118,
   Author = {L.S. Bennear and M. Baker-Goering and M. Lenox},
   Title = {The Effectiveness of Information Disclosure: An Examination
             of the TRI},
   Year = {2008},
   Key = {fds154118}
}

@article{fds154069,
   Author = {M.B. Sullivan and L.S. Bennear and W.E. Painter,
             Jr.},
   Title = {A Quasi-experimental Examination of Family Centered
             Treatment®: Outcomes for a Juvenile Delinquent
             Population},
   Year = {2008},
   Key = {fds154069}
}

@article{fds146419,
   Author = {L.S. Bennear and K.L. Dickinson},
   Title = {The Role of Program Evaluation in Environmental Policy: A
             Critical Evaluation of the Incentives Created by GPRA and
             PART.},
   Year = {2008},
   url = {http://www.duke.edu/~lds5/Papers/Bennear_Dickinson_GPRA_PART.pdf},
   Key = {fds146419}
}


Duke University * Arts & Sciences * Economics * Faculty * Research * Staff * Master's * Ph.D. * Reload * Login