Economics Faculty Database
Economics
Arts & Sciences
Duke University

 HOME > Arts & Sciences > Economics > Faculty    Search Help Login pdf version printable version 

Publications of Richard G. Newell    :chronological  alphabetical  combined listing:

%% Books   
@book{fds267080,
   Author = {Henderson, RM and Newell, RG},
   Title = {Accelerating Energy Innovation Insights from Multiple
             Sectors},
   Pages = {274 pages},
   Publisher = {University of Chicago Press},
   Year = {2011},
   Month = {May},
   ISBN = {0226326837},
   Abstract = {2010. International energy outlook2010. No.
             DOE/EIA-0484(2010). Washington, DC: Energy Information
             Administration. Gallagher, Kelly Sims, John P. Holdren, and
             Ambuj D. Sagar. 2006. Energy- technology innovation. Annual
             Review of ...},
   Key = {fds267080}
}

@book{fds267078,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Henderson, RM},
   Title = {Accelerating Energy Innovation: Insights from Multiple
             Sectors},
   Year = {2009},
   Month = {December},
   Abstract = {Accelerating the rate of innovation in energy is a critical
             component of any effective response to the threat of climate
             change. This book is designed to contribute to the debate as
             to how this can best be done through a focus on the history
             of four sectors of the US economy that have historically
             seen very rapid increases in the rate of innovation:
             agriculture, chemicals, life sciences, and information
             technology. In a sequence of seven chapters leading experts
             in the history of innovation in each sector explore the role
             that public and private policy has played in enabling
             accelerated innovation. Together they highlight the ways in
             which effective public policy in highly innovative sectors
             has been integrated (albeit rarely by design) into a complex
             innovation system that includes three critical elements: (1)
             substantial, differentiated, end-user demand that enables
             private firms commercializing the technology to anticipate
             healthy returns; (2) the sustained funding and effective
             management of fundamental research; and (3) the development
             of an institutional environment that includes robust
             mechanisms to promote the widespread diffusion of both
             knowledge and technology and that favors vigorous
             private-sector competition.},
   Key = {fds267078}
}


%% Book Chapters   
@misc{fds171210,
   Author = {Henderson, R.H and R.G. Newell},
   Title = {Accelerating Innovation in Energy: Insights from Multiple
             Sectors. Introduction and Summary},
   Year = {2011},
   Key = {fds171210}
}

@misc{fds171211,
   Author = {R.G. Newell},
   Title = {The Energy Innovation System: A Historical
             Perspective},
   Booktitle = {Accelerating Innovation in Energy: Insights from Multiple
             Sectors (R.H. Henderson and R.G. Newell,
             eds)},
   Year = {2009},
   Key = {fds171211}
}

@misc{fds152186,
   Author = {Jaffe, A.B. and R.G. Newell and R.N. Stavins},
   Title = {Technological change and the environment},
   Volume = {1},
   Series = {Handbooks in Economics series},
   Pages = {461-516},
   Booktitle = {Handbook of Environmental Economics},
   Publisher = {Amsterdam: North-Holland/Elsevier},
   Editor = {K.-G. Mäler and J. Vincent},
   Year = {2003},
   Key = {fds152186}
}

@misc{fds60875,
   Author = {Newell, R.G. and A.B. Jaffe and R.N. Stavins},
   Title = {The Induced Innovation Hypothesis and Energy-Saving
             Technological Change},
   Pages = {97-126},
   Booktitle = {Technological Change and the Environment},
   Publisher = {RFF Press, Washington, DC},
   Editor = {A. Grubler and N. Nakicenovic and W.D. Nordhaus},
   Year = {2002},
   url = {http://www.nicholas.duke.edu/people/faculty/newell/RFFbookch05-newell.pdf},
   Key = {fds60875}
}


%% Chapters in Books   
@misc{fds332954,
   Author = {Huang, B and Knox, M and Bradbury, K and Collins, LM and Newell,
             RG},
   Title = {Non-intrusive load monitoring system performance over a
             range of low frequency sampling rates},
   Journal = {2017 6th International Conference on Renewable Energy
             Research and Applications, Icrera 2017},
   Volume = {2017-January},
   Pages = {505-509},
   Publisher = {IEEE},
   Year = {2017},
   Month = {December},
   ISBN = {9781538620953},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1109/ICRERA.2017.8191111},
   Abstract = {Non-intrusive load monitoring (NILM) systems estimate the
             amount of energy each appliance consumes using as input the
             aggregate building energy consumption. Typically, NILM
             results are presented for a single sampling rate. To
             evaluate tradeoffs between end-uses and sensor costs, it is
             important to study the performance of NILM systems across
             sampling rates. In this work, we examine the performance of
             two NILM systems over a range of low frequency sampling
             rates on two datasets. Our results empirically demonstrate
             how NILM classification performance degrades nonlinearly as
             the sampling rate decreases and how varied this degradation
             is across appliance types. The results also suggest that
             reporting algorithm accuracy for a single sampling rate may
             not be sufficient for thorough algorithm performance
             evaluation. These findings can assist policy and decision
             makers in identifying the right smart meter hardware to meet
             appliance-level energy efficiency and building automation
             goals.},
   Doi = {10.1109/ICRERA.2017.8191111},
   Key = {fds332954}
}

@misc{fds330724,
   Author = {Malof, JM and Bradbury, K and Collins, LM and Newell, RG and Serrano, A and Wu, H and Keene, S},
   Title = {Image features for pixel-wise detection of solar
             photovoltaic arrays in aerial imagery using a random forest
             classifier},
   Journal = {2016 Ieee International Conference on Renewable Energy
             Research and Applications, Icrera 2016},
   Pages = {799-803},
   Publisher = {IEEE},
   Year = {2017},
   Month = {March},
   ISBN = {9781509033881},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1109/ICRERA.2016.7884446},
   Abstract = {Power generation from distributed solar photovoltaic (PV)
             arrays has grown rapidly in recent years. As a result, there
             is interest in collecting information about the quantity,
             power capacity, and energy generated by such arrays; and to
             do so over small geo-spatial regions (e.g., counties,
             cities, or even smaller regions). Unfortunately, existing
             sources of such information are dispersed, limited in
             geospatial resolution, and otherwise incomplete or
             publically unavailable. As result, we recently proposed a
             new approach for collecting such distributed PV information
             that relies on computer algorithms to automatically detect
             PV arrays in high resolution aerial imagery [1], Here, we
             build on this work by investigating a detection algorithm
             based on a Random Forest (RF) classifier, and we consider
             its detection performance using several different sets of
             image features. The proposed method is developed and tested
             using a very large collection of publicly available [2]
             aerial imagery, covering 112.5 km2 of surface area, with
             2,328 manually annotated PV array locations. The results
             indicate that a combination of local color and texture
             (using the popular texton feature) features yield the best
             detection performance.},
   Doi = {10.1109/ICRERA.2016.7884446},
   Key = {fds330724}
}

@misc{fds330726,
   Author = {Czarnek, N and Morton, K and Collins, L and Newell, R and Bradbury,
             K},
   Title = {Performance comparison framework for energy disaggregation
             systems},
   Journal = {2015 Ieee International Conference on Smart Grid
             Communications, Smartgridcomm 2015},
   Pages = {446-452},
   Publisher = {IEEE},
   Year = {2016},
   Month = {March},
   ISBN = {9781467382892},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1109/SmartGridComm.2015.7436341},
   Abstract = {Energy disaggregation algorithms decompose building-level
             energy data into device-level information. We conduct a
             head-To-head comparison of energy disaggregation techniques
             across multiple metrics and data sets. Our framework for
             analyzing the performance of a complete energy
             disaggregation system includes event detection,
             classification, and power assignment. We use receiver
             operating characteristics (ROCs) to evaluate event detection
             performance, and we introduce a technique to evaluate
             device-level event detection. We use confusion matrices to
             compare classification performance across several
             classifiers, and evaluate the resulting power assignments
             using several assignment metrics that are commonly used in
             the literature to demonstrate the varying strengths of the
             techniques that were considered. We apply this framework to
             several publicly available datasets and demonstrate how
             system performance varies with sampling frequency and the
             inclusion of reactive power. Our results suggest that (1)
             disaggregation performance varies considerably across data
             sets (2) increased data sampling rate improves
             disaggregation performance, and (3) additional features such
             as reactive power yields disaggregation performance
             improvements.},
   Doi = {10.1109/SmartGridComm.2015.7436341},
   Key = {fds330726}
}

@misc{fds330727,
   Author = {Malof, JM and Collins, LM and Bradbury, K and Newell,
             RG},
   Title = {A deep convolutional neural network and a random forest
             classifier for solar photovoltaic array detection in aerial
             imagery},
   Journal = {2016 Ieee International Conference on Renewable Energy
             Research and Applications, Icrera 2016},
   Pages = {650-654},
   Publisher = {IEEE},
   Year = {2016},
   Month = {January},
   ISBN = {9781509033881},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1109/ICRERA.2016.7884415},
   Abstract = {Power generation from distributed solar photovoltaic PV
             arrays has grown rapidly in recent years. As a result, there
             is interest in collecting information about the quantity,
             power capacity, and energy generated by such arrays; and to
             do so over small geo-spatial regions (e.g., counties,
             cities, or even smaller regions). Unfortunately, existing
             sources of such information are dispersed, limited in
             geospatial resolution, and otherwise incomplete or
             publically unavailable. As result, we recently proposed a
             new approach for collecting such distributed PV information
             that relies on computer algorithms to automatically detect
             PV arrays in high resolution aerial imagery [1], Here we
             build on this work by investigating two machine learning
             algorithms for PV array detection: a Random Forest
             classifier (RF) [2] and a deep convolutional neural network
             (CNN) [3]. We use the RF algorithm as a benchmark, or
             baseline, for comparison with a CNN model. The two models
             are developed and tested using a large collection of
             publicly available [4] aerial imagery, covering 135 km2, and
             including over 2,700 manually annotated distributed PV array
             locations. The results indicate that the CNN substantially
             improves over the RF. The CNN is capable of excellent
             performance, detecting nearly 80% of true panels with a
             precision measure of 72%.},
   Doi = {10.1109/ICRERA.2016.7884415},
   Key = {fds330727}
}

@misc{fds330339,
   Author = {Malof, JM and Hou, R and Collins, LM and Bradbury, K and Newell,
             R},
   Title = {Automatic solar photovoltaic panel detection in satellite
             imagery},
   Journal = {2015 International Conference on Renewable Energy Research
             and Applications, Icrera 2015},
   Pages = {1428-1431},
   Year = {2015},
   Month = {January},
   ISBN = {9781479999828},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1109/ICRERA.2015.7418643},
   Abstract = {The quantity of rooftop solar photovoltaic (PV)
             installations has grown rapidly in the US in recent years.
             There is a strong interest among decision makers in
             obtaining high quality information about rooftop PV, such as
             the locations, power capacity, and energy production of
             existing rooftop PV installations. Solar PV installations
             are typically connected directly to local power distribution
             grids, and therefore it is important for the reliable
             integration of solar energy to have information at high
             geospatial resolutions: by county, zip code, or even by
             neighborhood. Unfortunately, traditional means of obtaining
             this information, such as surveys and utility
             interconnection filings, are limited in availability and
             geospatial resolution. In this work a new approach is
             investigated where a computer vision algorithm is used to
             detect rooftop PV installations in high resolution color
             satellite imagery and aerial photography. It may then be
             possible to use the identified PV images to estimate power
             capacity and energy production for each array of panels,
             yielding a fast, scalable, and inexpensive method to obtain
             rooftop PV estimates for regions of any size. The aim of
             this work is to investigate the feasibility of the first
             step of the proposed approach: detecting rooftop PV in
             satellite imagery. Towards this goal, a collection of
             satellite rooftop images is used to develop and evaluate a
             detection algorithm. The results show excellent detection
             performance on the testing dataset and that, with further
             development, the proposed approach may be an effective
             solution for fast and scalable rooftop PV information
             collection.},
   Doi = {10.1109/ICRERA.2015.7418643},
   Key = {fds330339}
}


%% Articles   
@article{fds365722,
   Author = {Rennert, K and Errickson, F and Prest, BC and Rennels, L and Newell, RG and Pizer, W and Kingdon, C and Wingenroth, J and Cooke, R and Parthum, B and Smith, D and Cromar, K and Diaz, D and Moore, FC and Müller, UK and Plevin, RJ and Raftery, AE and Ševčíková, H and Sheets, H and Stock,
             JH and Tan, T and Watson, M and Wong, TE and Anthoff,
             D},
   Title = {Comprehensive evidence implies a higher social cost of
             CO2.},
   Journal = {Nature},
   Volume = {610},
   Number = {7933},
   Pages = {687-692},
   Publisher = {Springer Science and Business Media LLC},
   Year = {2022},
   Month = {October},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1038/s41586-022-05224-9},
   Abstract = {The social cost of carbon dioxide (SC-CO<sub>2</sub>)
             measures the monetized value of the damages to society
             caused by an incremental metric tonne of CO<sub>2</sub>
             emissions and is a key metric informing climate policy. Used
             by governments and other decision-makers in benefit-cost
             analysis for over a decade, SC-CO<sub>2</sub> estimates draw
             on climate science, economics, demography and other
             disciplines. However, a 2017 report by the US National
             Academies of Sciences, Engineering, and Medicine<sup>1</sup>
             (NASEM) highlighted that current SC-CO<sub>2</sub> estimates
             no longer reflect the latest research. The report provided a
             series of recommendations for improving the scientific
             basis, transparency and uncertainty characterization of
             SC-CO<sub>2</sub> estimates. Here we show that improved
             probabilistic socioeconomic projections, climate models,
             damage functions, and discounting methods that collectively
             reflect theoretically consistent valuation of risk,
             substantially increase estimates of the SC-CO<sub>2</sub>.
             Our preferred mean SC-CO<sub>2</sub> estimate is $185 per
             tonne of CO<sub>2</sub> ($44-$413 per tCO<sub>2</sub>:
             5%-95% range, 2020 US dollars) at a near-term risk-free
             discount rate of 2%, a value 3.6 times higher than the US
             government's current value of $51 per tCO<sub>2</sub>. Our
             estimates incorporate updated scientific understanding
             throughout all components of SC-CO<sub>2</sub> estimation in
             the new open-source Greenhouse Gas Impact Value Estimator
             (GIVE) model, in a manner fully responsive to the near-term
             NASEM recommendations. Our higher SC-CO<sub>2</sub> values,
             compared with estimates currently used in policy evaluation,
             substantially increase the estimated benefits of greenhouse
             gas mitigation and thereby increase the expected net
             benefits of more stringent climate policies.},
   Doi = {10.1038/s41586-022-05224-9},
   Key = {fds365722}
}

@article{fds365158,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Pizer, WA and Prest, BC},
   Title = {A discounting rule for the social cost of
             carbon},
   Journal = {Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource
             Economists},
   Volume = {9},
   Number = {5},
   Pages = {1017-1046},
   Year = {2022},
   Month = {September},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/718145},
   Abstract = {We develop a discounting rule for estimating the social cost
             of carbon (SCC) given uncertain economic growth. Diminishing
             marginal utility of income implies a relationship between
             the discount rate term structure and economic growth
             uncertainty. In the classic Ramsey framework, this
             relationship is governed by parameters reflecting pure time
             preference and the elasticity of the marginal utility of
             consumption, yet disagreement remains about the values of
             these parameters. We calibrate these parameters to match
             empirical evidence on both the future interest rate term
             structure and economic growth uncertainty, while also
             maintaining consistency with discount rates used for
             shorter-term benefit-cost analysis. Such an integrated
             approach is crucial amid growth uncertainty, where growth is
             also a key determinant of climate damages. This results in
             an empirically driven, stochastic discounting rule to be
             used in estimating the SCC that also accounts for the
             correlation between climate damage estimates and discount
             rates.},
   Doi = {10.1086/718145},
   Key = {fds365158}
}

@article{fds364287,
   Author = {Rennert, K and Prest, BC and Pizer, WA and Newell, RG and Anthoff, D and Kingdon, C and Rennels, L and Cooke, R and Raftery, AE and Ševčíková, H and Errickson, F},
   Title = {The Social Cost of Carbon: Advances in Long-Term
             Probabilistic Projections of Population, GDP, Emissions, and
             Discount Rates},
   Journal = {Brookings Papers on Economic Activity},
   Volume = {2021-Fall},
   Pages = {223-305},
   Year = {2021},
   Month = {September},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1353/eca.2022.0003},
   Abstract = {The social cost of carbon (SCC) is a crucial metric for
             inform-ing climate policy, most notably for guiding climate
             regulations issued by the US government. Characterization of
             uncertainty and transparency of assump-tions are critical
             for supporting such an influential metric. Challenges
             inherent to SCC estimation push the boundaries of typical
             analytical techniques and require augmented approaches to
             assess uncertainty, raising important considerations for
             discounting. This paper addresses the challenges of
             projecting very long-term economic growth, population, and
             greenhouse gas emissions, as well as cali-bration of
             discounting parameters for consistency with those
             projections. Our work improves on alternative approaches,
             such as nonprobabilistic scenarios and constant discounting,
             that have been used by the government but do not fully
             characterize the uncertainty distribution of fully
             probabilistic model input data or corresponding SCC estimate
             outputs. Incorporating the full range of economic
             uncertainty in the social cost of carbon underscores the
             importance of adopting a stochastic discounting approach to
             account for uncertainty in an integrated
             manner.},
   Doi = {10.1353/eca.2022.0003},
   Key = {fds364287}
}

@article{fds356873,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Prest, BC and Sexton, SE},
   Title = {The GDP-Temperature relationship: Implications for climate
             change damages},
   Journal = {Journal of Environmental Economics and Management},
   Volume = {108},
   Year = {2021},
   Month = {July},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2021.102445},
   Abstract = {Econometric models of temperature impacts on GDP are
             increasingly used to inform global warming damage
             assessments. But theory does not prescribe estimable forms
             of this relationship. By estimating 800 plausible
             specifications of the temperature-GDP relationship, we
             demonstrate that a wide variety of models are statistically
             indistinguishable in their out-of-sample performance,
             including models that exclude any temperature effect. This
             full set of models, however, implies a wide range of climate
             change impacts by 2100, yielding considerable model
             uncertainty. The uncertainty is greatest for models that
             specify effects of temperature on GDP growth that accumulate
             over time; the 95% confidence interval that accounts for
             both sampling and model uncertainty across the
             best-performing models ranges from 84% GDP losses to 359%
             gains. Models of GDP levels effects yield a much narrower
             distribution of GDP impacts centered around 1–3% losses,
             consistent with damage functions of major integrated
             assessment models. Further, models that incorporate lagged
             temperature effects are indicative of impacts on GDP levels
             rather than GDP growth. We identify statistically
             significant marginal effects of temperature on poor country
             GDP and agricultural production, but not rich country GDP,
             non-agricultural production, or GDP growth.},
   Doi = {10.1016/j.jeem.2021.102445},
   Key = {fds356873}
}

@article{fds342154,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Pizer, WA and Raimi, D},
   Title = {U.S. federal government subsidies for clean energy: Design
             choices and implications},
   Journal = {Energy Economics},
   Volume = {80},
   Pages = {831-841},
   Year = {2019},
   Month = {May},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2019.02.018},
   Abstract = {Subsidies for clean energy deployment have become a major
             component of U.S. federal energy and climate policy. After a
             surge in spending under the American Recovery and
             Reinvestment Act of 2009, they are an even larger component
             but now face increased scrutiny. Given their lasting
             presence, how does one design these subsidies to be as
             cost-effective as possible? Surprisingly, the conceptual
             framework and empirical evidence available to help
             policymakers identify which subsidies generate the most
             “bang for the buck” are limited. To help answer this
             question, we begin with an overview of the justifications
             for, and the arguments against, subsidizing clean energy
             technologies. Next, we briefly describe major subsidies.
             Finally, we summarize key design choices, suggesting an
             increased focus on upfront cash payments for physical
             outcomes such as capacity. This contrasts with the
             considerable focus on tax credits, loan guarantees,
             production, and cost-based subsidies which have been more
             prominent to date.},
   Doi = {10.1016/j.eneco.2019.02.018},
   Key = {fds342154}
}

@article{fds330725,
   Author = {Cao, J and Ho, MS and Li, Y and Newell, RG and Pizer,
             WA},
   Title = {Chinese residential electricity consumption: Estimation and
             forecast using micro-data},
   Journal = {Resource and Energy Economics},
   Volume = {56},
   Pages = {6-27},
   Publisher = {Elsevier BV},
   Year = {2019},
   Month = {May},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.reseneeco.2017.10.003},
   Abstract = {Based on econometric estimation using data from the Chinese
             Urban Household Survey, we develop a preferred forecast
             range of 85–143 percent growth in residential per capita
             electricity demand over 2009–2025. Our analysis suggests
             that per capita income growth drives a 43% increase, with
             the remainder due to an unexplained time trend. Roughly
             one-third of the income-driven demand comes from increases
             in the stock of specific major appliances, particularly AC
             units. The other two-thirds comes from non-specific sources
             of income-driven growth and is based on an estimated income
             elasticity that falls from 0.28 to 0.11 as income rises.
             While the stock of refrigerators is not projected to
             increase, we find that they contribute nearly 20 percent of
             household electricity demand. Alternative plausible time
             trend assumptions are responsible for the wide range of
             85–143 percent. Meanwhile we estimate a price elasticity
             of demand of −0.7. These estimates point to carbon pricing
             and appliance efficiency policies that could substantially
             reduce demand.},
   Doi = {10.1016/j.reseneeco.2017.10.003},
   Key = {fds330725}
}

@article{fds333902,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Prest, BC},
   Title = {The unconventional oil supply boom: Aggregate price response
             from microdata},
   Journal = {The Energy Journal},
   Volume = {40},
   Number = {3},
   Pages = {1-30},
   Publisher = {International Association for Energy Economics
             (IAEE)},
   Year = {2019},
   Month = {January},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.5547/01956574.40.3.rnew},
   Abstract = {We analyze the price responsiveness of U.S. conventional and
             unconventional oil supply across three key stages of oil
             production: Drilling, completion, and production. Drilling
             is the most important margin, with price elasticities of 1.3
             and 1.6 for conventional and unconventional drilling
             respectively. Well productivity declines as prices rise,
             implying smaller net supply elasticities of about 1.1 and
             1.2. Despite similar supply elasticities, the price response
             of unconventional supply is larger in terms of barrels
             because of much higher production per well (∼10x
             initially). Oil supply simulations show a 13-fold larger
             supply response due to the shale revolution. The simulations
             suggest that a price rise from $50 to $80 per barrel induces
             incremental U.S. production of 0.6MM barrels per day in 6
             months, 1.4MM in 1 year, 2.4MM in 2 years, and 4.2MM in 5
             years. Nonetheless, the response takes much longer than the
             30 to 90 days than typically associated with the role of
             'swing producer'.},
   Doi = {10.5547/01956574.40.3.rnew},
   Key = {fds333902}
}

@article{fds333535,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Raimi, D},
   Title = {The fiscal impacts of increased U.S. oil and gas development
             on local governments},
   Journal = {Energy Policy},
   Volume = {117},
   Pages = {14-24},
   Publisher = {Elsevier BV},
   Year = {2018},
   Month = {June},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2018.02.042},
   Abstract = {Increased US oil and gas production has created
             opportunities and challenges for local governments. Through
             interviews with roughly 250 local officials, we evaluate the
             fiscal effects of this development in 21 regions across
             every major US oil and gas producing state during “boom”
             and “bust” periods. Growing oil and gas production has
             increased local government revenues through a variety of
             mechanisms, including property taxes, sales taxes, severance
             taxes, and more. Industry activity has also increased costs
             and demand for local services led by road damage, water and
             wastewater infrastructure, and a range of staff costs
             including emergency services and law enforcement. Despite
             volatility in revenues and service demands, our interview
             results show that 74% of local governments have experienced
             net fiscal benefits, 14% reported roughly neutral effects,
             and 12% reported net fiscal costs. Local governments in
             highly rural regions experiencing large-scale growth have
             faced the greatest challenges. To further improve future
             outcomes, local officials can plan for impacts, state
             policymakers can re-examine revenue policies, and operators
             can pursue collaboration with local governments.},
   Doi = {10.1016/j.enpol.2018.02.042},
   Key = {fds333535}
}

@article{fds333908,
   Author = {Bielen, DA and Newell, RG and Pizer, WA},
   Title = {Who did the ethanol tax credit benefit? An event analysis of
             subsidy incidence},
   Journal = {Journal of Public Economics},
   Volume = {161},
   Pages = {1-14},
   Publisher = {Elsevier BV},
   Year = {2018},
   Month = {May},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2018.03.005},
   Abstract = {At the end of 2011, the Volumetric Ethanol Excise Tax Credit
             (VEETC), which had subsidized the blending of ethanol in
             gasoline, was allowed to expire. During its tenure, the
             subsidy was the subject of intense scrutiny concerning who
             benefited from its existence. Using commodity price data, we
             estimate the subsidy incidence accruing to corn farmers,
             ethanol producers, gasoline blenders, and gasoline consumers
             around the time of expiration. Our empirical approach
             contributes methodologically to the event studies literature
             by analyzing futures contract prices (as opposed to spot
             prices) when possible. Ultimately, we find compelling
             evidence that, at the date of VEETC expiration, ethanol
             producers captured about 25¢ of the 45¢ subsidy per gallon
             of ethanol blended. We find suggestive, albeit inconclusive,
             evidence that a portion of this benefit (about 5¢ per
             gallon) was passed further upstream from ethanol producers
             to corn farmers. Most of the remainder seems most likely to
             have been captured by the blenders themselves. On the
             petroleum side, we find no evidence that oil refiners
             captured any part of the subsidy. We also find no evidence
             that the subsidy was passed downstream to gasoline consumers
             in the form of lower gasoline prices.},
   Doi = {10.1016/j.jpubeco.2018.03.005},
   Key = {fds333908}
}

@article{fds267050,
   Author = {Kerr, S and Newell, RG},
   Title = {Policy-induced technology adoption: Evidence from the U.S.
             lead phasedown},
   Pages = {193-219},
   Year = {2018},
   Month = {January},
   ISBN = {9780815388227},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.4324/9781351161084-11},
   Abstract = {Theory suggests that economic instruments, such as pollution
             taxes or tradable permits, can provide more efficient
             technology adoption incentives than conventional regulatory
             standards. We explore this issue for an important industry
             undergoing dramatic decreases in allowed pollution - the
             U.S. petroleum industry’s phasedown of lead in gasoline.
             Using a duration model applied to a panel of refineries from
             1971-1995, we find that the pattern of technology adoption
             is consistent with an economic response to market
             incentives, plant characteristics, and alternative policies.
             Importantly, evidence suggests that the tradable permit
             system used during the phasedown provided incentives for
             more efficient technology adoption decisions.},
   Doi = {10.4324/9781351161084-11},
   Key = {fds267050}
}

@article{fds330723,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Raimi, D},
   Title = {US state and local oil and gas revenue sources and
             uses},
   Journal = {Energy Policy},
   Volume = {112},
   Pages = {12-18},
   Publisher = {Elsevier BV},
   Year = {2018},
   Month = {January},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2017.10.002},
   Abstract = {US state and local governments generate revenues from oil
             and gas production through a variety of mechanisms. In this
             paper, we quantify four leading sources: (1) state taxes
             levied on the value or volume of oil and gas produced; (2)
             local property taxes levied on the value of oil and gas
             property; (3) oil and gas lease revenues from state lands;
             and (4) oil and gas lease revenues from federal lands. We
             measure these revenues against the total value of oil and
             gas produced in the top 16 oil- and gas-producing states
             using fiscal year 2013 as a benchmark. On average, state and
             local governments collect roughly 10% of oil and gas
             revenue, ranging from a low of roughly 1% to a high of
             nearly 40% (not including income taxes). We also assess the
             use of these revenues, finding that there is substantial
             variation among states. The largest shares of revenue flow
             to state governments’ current expenditures and education,
             followed by local governments. Some states also allocate a
             portion of oil and gas revenues to trust funds endowing
             future government operations and/or education
             expenditures.},
   Doi = {10.1016/j.enpol.2017.10.002},
   Key = {fds330723}
}

@article{fds267085,
   Author = {Gerarden, TD and Newell, RG and Stavins, RN},
   Title = {Assessing the energy-efficiency gap},
   Journal = {Journal of Economic Literature},
   Volume = {55},
   Number = {4},
   Pages = {1486-1525},
   Publisher = {American Economic Association},
   Year = {2017},
   Month = {December},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/jel.20161360},
   Abstract = {Energy-efficient technologies offer considerable promise for
             reducing the financial costs and environmental damages
             associated with energy use, but it has long been observed
             that these technologies may not be adopted by individuals
             and firms to the degree that might be justified, even on a
             purely financial basis. We survey the relevant literature on
             this "energy-efficiency gap" by presenting two complementary
             frameworks. First, we divide potential explanations for the
             energy-efficiency gap into three categories: market
             failures, behavioral explanations, and model and measurement
             errors. Second, we organize previous research in terms of
             the fundamental elements of cost-minimizing
             energy-efficiency decisions. This provides a decomposition
             that organizes thinking around four questions. First, are
             product offerings and pricing economically efficient?
             Second, are energy operating costs inefficiently priced
             and/or understood? Third, are product choices cost
             minimizing in present value terms? Fourth, do other costs
             inhibit more energy-efficient decisions? We synthesize
             academic research on these questions, with an emphasis on
             recent empirical findings, and offer suggestions for future
             research. ( JEL D24, D82, L94, L98, O33, Q41,
             Q48).},
   Doi = {10.1257/jel.20161360},
   Key = {fds267085}
}

@article{fds347655,
   Author = {Fischer, C and Preonas, L and Newell, RG},
   Title = {Environmental and technology policy options in the
             electricity sector: Are we deploying too
             many?},
   Journal = {Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource
             Economists},
   Volume = {4},
   Number = {4},
   Pages = {959-984},
   Year = {2017},
   Month = {December},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/692507},
   Abstract = {Myriad policy measures aim to reduce greenhouse gas
             emissions from the electricity sector, promote generation
             from renewable sources, and encourage energy efficiency
             (EE). Prior literature has argued that overlapping policies
             reduce the efficiency of emissions markets, absent other
             market failures. We extend the model of Fischer and Newell
             to incorporate knowledge spillovers for both advanced and
             conventional renewable energy technologies, as well as
             imperfections in demand for EE investments. EE
             undervaluation can justify interventions and raises the
             importance of fully pricing the social costs of electricity,
             making policies (like renewable subsidies) that lower
             electricity prices less desirable. Innovation market
             failures justify some technology policies, particularly
             correcting R&D incentives, but aggressive deployment
             policies seem unlikely to enhance welfare when placed
             alongside sufficient emissions pricing. Even with multiple
             market failures, emissions pricing remains the most
             cost-effective option for reducing emissions. However,
             technology-oriented policies can involve less redistribution
             of surplus.},
   Doi = {10.1086/692507},
   Key = {fds347655}
}

@article{fds333900,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Prest, B},
   Title = {Informing SPR Policy Through Oil Futures and Inventory
             Dynamics},
   Year = {2017},
   Month = {November},
   Key = {fds333900}
}

@article{fds333901,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Prest, B},
   Title = {Informing SPR Policy Through Oil Futures and Inventory
             Dynamics},
   Journal = {Ssrn Electronic Journal},
   Publisher = {Elsevier BV},
   Year = {2017},
   Month = {October},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3094419},
   Doi = {10.2139/ssrn.3094419},
   Key = {fds333901}
}

@article{fds333903,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Prest, B},
   Title = {Is the US the New Swing Producer? The Price Responsiveness
             of Tight Oil},
   Journal = {Ssrn Electronic Journal},
   Number = {17},
   Publisher = {Elsevier BV},
   Year = {2017},
   Month = {June},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3093968},
   Doi = {10.2139/ssrn.3093968},
   Key = {fds333903}
}

@article{fds330013,
   Author = {Bradbury, K and Saboo, R and Johnson, TL and Malof, JM and Devarajan, A and Zhang, W and Collins, LM and Newell, RG},
   Title = {Distributed solar photovoltaic array location and extent
             dataset for remote sensing object identification},
   Journal = {Scientific Data},
   Volume = {3},
   Pages = {160106},
   Year = {2016},
   Month = {December},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1038/sdata.2016.106},
   Abstract = {Earth-observing remote sensing data, including aerial
             photography and satellite imagery, offer a snapshot of the
             world from which we can learn about the state of natural
             resources and the built environment. The components of
             energy systems that are visible from above can be
             automatically assessed with these remote sensing data when
             processed with machine learning methods. Here, we focus on
             the information gap in distributed solar photovoltaic (PV)
             arrays, of which there is limited public data on solar PV
             deployments at small geographic scales. We created a dataset
             of solar PV arrays to initiate and develop the process of
             automatically identifying solar PV locations using remote
             sensing imagery. This dataset contains the geospatial
             coordinates and border vertices for over 19,000 solar panels
             across 601 high-resolution images from four cities in
             California. Dataset applications include training object
             detection and other machine learning algorithms that use
             remote sensing imagery, developing specific algorithms for
             predictive detection of distributed PV systems, estimating
             installed PV capacity, and analysis of the socioeconomic
             correlates of PV deployment.},
   Doi = {10.1038/sdata.2016.106},
   Key = {fds330013}
}

@article{fds330014,
   Author = {Malof, JM and Bradbury, K and Collins, LM and Newell,
             RG},
   Title = {Automatic detection of solar photovoltaic arrays in high
             resolution aerial imagery},
   Journal = {Applied Energy},
   Volume = {183},
   Pages = {229-240},
   Publisher = {Elsevier BV},
   Year = {2016},
   Month = {December},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.apenergy.2016.08.191},
   Abstract = {The quantity of small scale solar photovoltaic (PV) arrays
             in the United States has grown rapidly in recent years. As a
             result, there is substantial interest in high quality
             information about the quantity, power capacity, and energy
             generated by such arrays, including at a high spatial
             resolution (e.g., cities, counties, or other small regions).
             Unfortunately, existing methods for obtaining this
             information, such as surveys and utility interconnection
             filings, are limited in their completeness and spatial
             resolution. This work presents a computer algorithm that
             automatically detects PV panels using very high resolution
             color satellite imagery. The approach potentially offers a
             fast, scalable method for obtaining accurate information on
             PV array location and size, and at much higher spatial
             resolutions than are currently available. The method is
             validated using a very large (135 km2) collection of
             publicly available (Bradbury et al., 2016) aerial imagery,
             with over 2700 human annotated PV array locations. The
             results demonstrate the algorithm is highly effective on a
             per-pixel basis. It is likewise effective at object-level PV
             array detection, but with significant potential for
             improvement in estimating the precise shape/size of the PV
             arrays. These results are the first of their kind for the
             detection of solar PV in aerial imagery, demonstrating the
             feasibility of the approach and establishing a baseline
             performance for future investigations.},
   Doi = {10.1016/j.apenergy.2016.08.191},
   Key = {fds330014}
}

@article{fds333904,
   Author = {Raimi, D and Newell, RG},
   Title = {US State and Local Oil and Gas Revenues},
   Year = {2016},
   Month = {November},
   Key = {fds333904}
}

@article{fds333907,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Prest, B and Vissing, A},
   Title = {Trophy Hunting vs. Manufacturing Energy: The
             Price-Responsiveness of Shale Gas},
   Year = {2016},
   Month = {August},
   Key = {fds333907}
}

@article{fds361696,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Raimi, D},
   Title = {Local government revenue from oil and gas
             production},
   Year = {2016},
   Month = {June},
   Abstract = {Oil and gas production generates substantial revenue for
             state and local governments. This report examines revenue
             from oil and gas production flowing to local governments
             through four mechanisms: (i) state taxes or fees on oil and
             gas production; (ii) local property taxes on oil and gas
             property; (iii) leasing of state-owned land; and (iv)
             leasing of federally owned land. We examine every major oil-
             and gas-producing state and find that the share of oil and
             gas production value allocated to and collected by local
             governments ranges widely, from 0.5 percent to more than 9
             percent due to numerous policy differences among states.
             School districts and trust funds endowing future school
             operations tend to see the highest share of revenue,
             followed by counties. Municipalities and other local
             governments with more limited geographic boundaries tend to
             receive smaller shares of oil and gas driven revenue. Some
             states utilize grant programs to allocate revenue to where
             impacts from the industry are greatest. Others send most
             revenue to state operating or trust funds, with little
             revenue earmarked specifically for local
             governments.},
   Key = {fds361696}
}

@article{fds361697,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Raimi, D},
   Title = {Local fiscal effects of oil and gas development in eight
             states},
   Year = {2016},
   Month = {June},
   Abstract = {Oil and gas production in the United States has increased
             dramatically in the past 10 years. This growth has important
             implications for local governments, which often see new
             revenues from a variety of sources: property taxes on oil
             and gas property, sales taxes driven by the oil and gas
             workforce, allocations of state revenues from severance
             taxes or state and federal leases, leases on local
             government land, and contributions from oil and gas
             companies to support local services. At the same time, local
             governments tend to experience a range of new costs such as
             road damage caused by heavy industry truck traffic,
             increased demand for emergency services and law enforcement,
             and challenges with workforce retention. This report
             examines county and municipal fiscal effects in 14 oil- and
             gas-producing regions of eight states: AK, CA, KS, OH, OK,
             NM, UT, and WV. We find that for most local governments, oil
             and gas development—whether new or longstanding—has a
             positive effect on local public finances. However, effects
             can vary substantially due to a variety of local factors and
             policy issues. For some local governments, particularly
             those in rural regions experiencing large increases in
             development, revenues have not kept pace with rapidly
             increased costs and demand for services, particularly on
             road repair. Duke University Energy Initiative working
             paper; May 2016.},
   Key = {fds361697}
}

@article{fds361699,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Raimi, D},
   Title = {Dunn County and Watford City, North Dakota: A case study of
             the fiscal effects of Bakken shale development},
   Publisher = {Duke University Energy Initiative},
   Year = {2016},
   Month = {May},
   Abstract = {The Bakken region of North Dakota and Montana has
             experienced perhaps the greatest effects of increased oil
             and gas development in the United States, with major
             implications for local governments. Though development of
             the Bakken began in the early 2000s, large-scale drilling
             and population growth dramatically affected the region from
             roughly 2008 through today. This case study examines the
             local government fiscal benefits and challenges experienced
             by Dunn County and Watford City, which lie near the heart of
             the producing region. For both local governments, the
             initial growth phase presented major fiscal challenges due
             to rapidly expanding service demands and insufficient
             revenue. In the following years, these challenges eased as
             demand for services slowed due to declining industry
             activity and state tax policies redirected more funds to
             localities. Looking forward, both local governments describe
             their fiscal health as stronger because of the Bakken boom,
             though higher debt loads and an economy heavily dependent on
             the volatile oil and gas industry each pose challenges for
             future fiscal stability.},
   Key = {fds361699}
}

@article{fds361698,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Raimi, D},
   Title = {Colorado's Piceance Basin: Variation in the local public
             finance effects of oil and gas development},
   Publisher = {Duke University Energy Initiative},
   Year = {2016},
   Month = {May},
   Abstract = {A large increase in natural gas production occurred in
             western Colorado’s Piceance basin in the mid- to
             late-2000s, generating a surge in population, economic
             activity, and heavy truck traffic in this rural region. We
             describe the fiscal effects related to this development for
             two county governments: Garfield and Rio Blanco, and two
             city governments: Grand Junction and Rifle. Counties
             maintain rural road networks in Colorado, and Garfield
             County’s ability to fashion agreements with operators to
             repair roads damaged during operations helped prevent the
             types of large new costs seen in Rio Blanco County, a
             neighboring county with less government capacity and where
             such agreements were not made. Rifle and Grand Junction
             experienced substantial oil- and gas-driven population
             growth, with greater challenges in the smaller, more
             isolated, and less economically diverse city of Rifle.
             Lessons from this case study include the value of crafting
             road maintenance agreements, fiscal risks for small and
             geographically isolated communities experiencing rapid
             population growth, challenges associated with limited
             infrastructure, and the desirability of flexibility in the
             allocation of oil- and gas-related revenue.},
   Key = {fds361698}
}

@article{fds267074,
   Author = {Gerarden, T and Newell, RG and Stavins, RN},
   Title = {Deconstructing the energy efficiency gap: Conceptual
             frameworks and evidence},
   Journal = {American Economic Review},
   Volume = {105},
   Number = {5},
   Pages = {183-186},
   Publisher = {American Economic Association},
   Year = {2015},
   Month = {May},
   ISSN = {0002-8282},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/10273 Duke open
             access},
   Doi = {10.1257/aer.p20151012},
   Key = {fds267074}
}

@article{fds267083,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Siikamki, J},
   Title = {Individual time preferences and energy efficiency},
   Journal = {American Economic Review},
   Volume = {105},
   Number = {5},
   Pages = {196-200},
   Publisher = {American Economic Association},
   Year = {2015},
   Month = {May},
   ISSN = {0002-8282},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/10274 Duke open
             access},
   Doi = {10.1257/aer.p20151010},
   Key = {fds267083}
}

@article{fds267045,
   Author = {Gerarden, T and Newell, RG and Stavins, RN},
   Title = {Assessing the Energy-Efficiency Gap},
   Journal = {Feem Working Paper},
   Number = {035},
   Year = {2015},
   Month = {April},
   Abstract = {Energy-efficient technologies offer considerable promise for
             reducing the financial costs and environmental damages
             associated with energy use, but these technologies appear
             not to be adopted by consumers and businesses to the degree
             that would apparently be justified, even on a purely
             financial basis. We present two complementary frameworks for
             understanding this so-called “energy paradox” or
             “energy-efficiency gap.” First, we build on the previous
             literature by dividing potential explanations for the
             energy-efficiency gap into three categories: market
             failures, behavioral anomalies, and model and measurement
             errors. Second, we posit that it is useful to think in terms
             of the fundamental elements of cost-minimizing
             energy-efficiency decisions. This provides a decomposition
             that organizes thinking around four questions. First, are
             product offerings and pricing economically efficient?
             Second, are energy operating costs inefficiently priced
             and/or understood? Third, are product choices
             cost-minimizing in present value terms? Fourth, do other
             costs inhibit more energy-efficient decisions? We review
             empirical evidence on these questions, with an emphasis on
             recent advances, and offer suggestions for future
             research.},
   Key = {fds267045}
}

@article{fds267076,
   Author = {Gerarden, T and Newell, RG and Stavins, RN and Stowe,
             R},
   Title = {An Assessment of the Energy-Efficiency Gap and Its
             Implications for Climate Change Policy},
   Year = {2015},
   Month = {April},
   Abstract = {Improving end-use energy efficiency — that is, the
             energy-efficiency of individuals, households, and firms as
             they consume energy — is often cited as an important
             element in efforts to reduce greenhouse-gas (GHG) emissions.
             Arguments for improving energy efficiency usually rely on
             the idea that energy-efficient technologies will save end
             users money over time and thereby provide low-cost or
             no-cost options for reducing GHG emissions. However, some
             research suggests that energy-efficient technologies appear
             not to be adopted by consumers and businesses to the degree
             that would seem justified, even on a purely financial basis.
             We review in this paper the evidence for a range of
             explanations for this apparent “energy-efficiency gap.”
             We find most explanations are grounded in sound economic
             theory, but the strength of empirical support for these
             explanations varies widely. Retrospective program
             evaluations suggest the cost of GHG abatement varies
             considerably across different energy-efficiency investments
             and can diverge substantially from the predictions of
             prospective models. Findings from research on the
             energy-efficiency gap could help policy makers generate
             social and private benefits from accelerating the diffusion
             of energy-efficient technologies — including reduction of
             GHG emissions.},
   Key = {fds267076}
}

@article{fds267075,
   Author = {Gerarden, T and Newell, RG and Stavins, RN},
   Title = {Assessing the Energy-Efficiency Gap},
   Year = {2015},
   Month = {January},
   Abstract = {Energy-efficient technologies offer considerable promise for
             reducing the financial costs and environmental damages
             associated with energy use, but these technologies appear
             not to be adopted by consumers and businesses to the degree
             that would apparently be justified, even on a purely
             financial basis. We present two complementary frameworks for
             understanding this so-called “energy paradox” or
             “energy-efficiency gap.” First, we build on the previous
             literature by dividing potential explanations for the
             energy-efficiency gap into three categories: market
             failures, behavioral anomalies, and model and measurement
             errors. Second, we posit that it is useful to think in terms
             of the fundamental elements of cost-minimizing
             energy-efficiency decisions. This provides a decomposition
             that organizes thinking around four questions. First, are
             product offerings and pricing economically efficient?
             Second, are energy operating costs inefficiently priced
             and/or understood? Third, are product choices
             cost-minimizing in present value terms? Fourth, do other
             costs inhibit more energy-efficient decisions? We review
             empirical evidence on these questions, with an emphasis on
             recent advances, and offer suggestions for future
             research.},
   Key = {fds267075}
}

@article{fds267086,
   Author = {Gerarden, T and Newell, RG and Stavins, RN and Stowe,
             R},
   Title = {An Assessment of the Energy-Efficiency Gap and its
             Implications for Climate-Change Policy},
   Year = {2015},
   Month = {January},
   Abstract = {Improving end-use energy efficiency—that is, the
             energy-efficiency of individuals, households, and firms as
             they consume energy—is often cited as an important element
             in efforts to reduce greenhouse-gas (GHG) emissions.
             Arguments for improving energy efficiency usually rely on
             the idea that energy-efficient technologies will save end
             users money over time and thereby provide low-cost or
             no-cost options for reducing GHG emissions. However, some
             research suggests that energy-efficient technologies appear
             not to be adopted by consumers and businesses to the degree
             that would seem justified, even on a purely financial basis.
             We review in this paper the evidence for a range of
             explanations for this apparent “energy-efficiency gap.”
             We find most explanations are grounded in sound economic
             theory, but the strength of empirical support for these
             explanations varies widely. Retrospective program
             evaluations suggest the cost of GHG abatement varies
             considerably across different energy-efficiency investments
             and can diverge substantially from the predictions of
             prospective models. Findings from research on the
             energy-efficiency gap could help policy makers generate
             social and private benefits from accelerating the diffusion
             of energy-efficient technologies—including reduction of
             GHG emissions.<br><br>Institutional subscribers to the NBER
             working paper series, and residents of developing countries
             may download this paper without additional charge at <a
             href="http://www.nber.org/papers/&#119??20905"
             TARGET="_blank">www.nber.org</a>.<br>},
   Key = {fds267086}
}

@article{fds267089,
   Author = {Pizer, W and Adler, M and Aldy, J and Anthoff, D and Cropper, M and Gillingham, K and Greenstone, M and Murray, B and Newell, R and Richels,
             R and Rowell, A and Waldhoff, S and Wiener, J},
   Title = {Using and improving the social cost of carbon},
   Journal = {Science (New York, N.Y.)},
   Volume = {346},
   Number = {6214},
   Pages = {1189-1190},
   Year = {2014},
   Month = {December},
   ISSN = {0036-8075},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/10259 Duke open
             access},
   Doi = {10.1126/science.1259774},
   Key = {fds267089}
}

@article{fds267082,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Siikamäki, J},
   Title = {Nudging Energy Efficiency Behavior: The Role of Information
             Labels},
   Pages = {555-598},
   Publisher = {University of Chicago Press},
   Year = {2014},
   Month = {December},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/679281},
   Abstract = {This report evaluates the effectiveness of energy efficiency
             labels in guiding household decisions. Using a choice
             experiment with alternative labels, the authors find that
             simple information on the economic value of saving energy is
             the most important element guiding more cost-efficient
             investments in appliance energy efficiency; information on
             physical energy use and carbon emissions has no significant
             additional value. They also find that the degree to which
             the current EnergyGuide label guides cost-efficient
             decisions depends on the assumed discount rate. These
             results reinforce the importance of intertemporal choice and
             discounting for understanding individual behavior and
             guiding policy.},
   Doi = {10.1086/679281},
   Key = {fds267082}
}

@article{fds267046,
   Author = {Gerarden, T and Newell, RG and Stavins, RN and Stowe,
             R},
   Title = {An Assessment of the Energy-Efficiency Gap and Its
             Implications for Climate-Change Policy},
   Year = {2014},
   Month = {November},
   Abstract = {Improving end-use energy efficiency — that is, the
             energy-efficiency of individuals, households, and firms as
             they consume energy — is often cited as an important
             element in efforts to reduce greenhouse-gas (GHG) emissions.
             Arguments for improving energy efficiency usually rely on
             the idea that energy-efficient technologies will save end
             users money over time and thereby provide low-cost or
             no-cost options for reducing GHG emissions. However, some
             research suggests that energy-efficient technologies appear
             not to be adopted by consumers and businesses to the degree
             that would seem justified, even on a purely financial basis.
             We review in this paper the evidence for a range of
             explanations for this apparent “energy-efficiency gap.”
             We find most explanations are grounded in sound economic
             theory, but the strength of empirical support for these
             explanations varies widely. Retrospective program
             evaluations suggest the cost of GHG abatement varies
             considerably across different energy-efficiency investments
             and can diverge substantially from the predictions of
             prospective models. Findings from research on the
             energy-efficiency gap could help policy makers generate
             social and private benefits from accelerating the diffusion
             of energy-efficient technologies — including reduction of
             GHG emissions.},
   Key = {fds267046}
}

@article{fds267090,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Pizer, WA and Raimi, D},
   Title = {Carbon markets: Past, present, and future},
   Journal = {Annual Review of Resource Economics},
   Volume = {6},
   Number = {1},
   Pages = {191-215},
   Publisher = {ANNUAL REVIEWS},
   Year = {2014},
   Month = {October},
   ISSN = {1941-1340},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/10262 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {Carbon markets are substantial and expanding. There are many
             lessons from experience over the past 9 years: fewer free
             allowances, careful moderation of low and high prices, and a
             recognition that trading systems require adjustments that
             have consequences for market participants and market
             confidence. Moreover, the emerging international
             architecture features separate emissions trading systems
             serving distinct jurisdictions. These programs are
             complemented by a variety of other types of policies
             alongside the carbon markets. This architecture sits in
             sharp contrast to the integrated global trading architecture
             envisioned 15 years ago by the designers of the Kyoto
             Protocol and raises a suite of new questions. In this new
             architecture, jurisdictions with emissions trading have to
             decide how, whether, and when to link with one another, and
             policy makers must confront how to measure both the
             comparability of efforts among markets and the comparability
             between markets and a variety of other policy
             approaches.},
   Doi = {10.1146/annurev-resource-100913-012655},
   Key = {fds267090}
}

@article{fds267096,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Raimi, D},
   Title = {Implications of shale gas development for climate
             change},
   Journal = {Environmental Science & Technology},
   Volume = {48},
   Number = {15},
   Pages = {8360-8368},
   Year = {2014},
   Month = {August},
   ISSN = {0013-936X},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/10263 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {Advances in technologies for extracting oil and gas from
             shale formations have dramatically increased U.S. production
             of natural gas. As production expands domestically and
             abroad, natural gas prices will be lower than without shale
             gas. Lower prices have two main effects: increasing overall
             energy consumption, and encouraging substitution away from
             sources such as coal, nuclear, renewables, and electricity.
             We examine the evidence and analyze modeling projections to
             understand how these two dynamics affect greenhouse gas
             emissions. Most evidence indicates that natural gas as a
             substitute for coal in electricity production, gasoline in
             transport, and electricity in buildings decreases greenhouse
             gases, although as an electricity substitute this depends on
             the electricity mix displaced. Modeling suggests that absent
             substantial policy changes, increased natural gas production
             slightly increases overall energy use, more substantially
             encourages fuel-switching, and that the combined effect
             slightly alters economy wide GHG emissions; whether the net
             effect is a slight decrease or increase depends on modeling
             assumptions including upstream methane emissions. Our main
             conclusions are that natural gas can help reduce GHG
             emissions, but in the absence of targeted climate policy
             measures, it will not substantially change the course of
             global GHG concentrations. Abundant natural gas can,
             however, help reduce the costs of achieving GHG reduction
             goals. © 2014 American Chemical Society.},
   Doi = {10.1021/es4046154},
   Key = {fds267096}
}

@article{fds267079,
   Author = {Fischer, C and Newell, RG and Preonas, L},
   Title = {Environmental and Technology Policy Options in the
             Electricity Sector: Interactions and Outcomes},
   Year = {2014},
   Month = {July},
   Abstract = {Myriad policy measures aim to reduce greenhouse gas
             emissions from the electricity sector, promote generation
             from renewable sources, and encourage energy conservation.
             To what extent do innovation and energy efficiency (EE)
             market failures justify additional interventions when a
             carbon price is in place? We extend the model of Fischer and
             Newell (2008) with advanced and conventional renewable
             energy technologies and short and long-run EE investments.
             We incorporate both knowledge spillovers and imperfections
             in the demand for energy efficiency. We conclude that some
             technology policies, particularly correcting R&D market
             failures, can be useful complements to emissions pricing,
             but ambitious renewable targets or subsidies seem unlikely
             to enhance welfare when placed alongside sufficient
             emissions pricing. The desirability of stringent EE policies
             is highly sensitive to the degree of undervaluation of EE by
             consumers, which also has implications for policies that
             tend to lower electricity prices Even with multiple market
             failures, emissions pricing remains the single most
             cost-effective option for reducing emissions.},
   Key = {fds267079}
}

@article{fds267069,
   Author = {Fischer, C and Newell, RG and Preonas, L},
   Title = {Environmental and Technology Policy Options in the
             Electricity Sector: Interactions and Outcomes},
   Year = {2014},
   Month = {April},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/10753 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {Myriad policy measures aim to reduce greenhouse gas
             emissions from the electricity sector, promote generation
             from renewable sources, and encourage energy conservation.
             To what extent do innovation and energy efficiency (EE)
             market failures justify additional interventions when a
             carbon price is in place? We extend the model of Fischer and
             Newell (2008) with advanced and conventional renewable
             energy technologies and short and long-run EE investments.
             We incorporate both knowledge spillovers and imperfections
             in the demand for energy efficiency. We conclude that some
             technology policies, particularly correcting R&D market
             failures, can be useful complements to emissions pricing,
             but ambitious renewable targets or subsidies seem unlikely
             to enhance welfare when placed alongside sufficient
             emissions pricing. The desirability of stringent EE policies
             is highly sensitive to the degree of undervaluation of EE by
             consumers, which also has implications for policies that
             tend to lower electricity prices. Even with multiple market
             failures, emissions pricing remains the single most
             cost-effective option for reducing emissions.},
   Key = {fds267069}
}

@article{fds267094,
   Author = {Arrow, KJ and Cropper, ML and Gollier, C and Groom, B and Heal, GM and Newell, RG and Nordhaus, WD and Pindyck, RS and Pizer, WA and Portney,
             PR and Sterner, T and Tol, RSJ and Weitzman, ML},
   Title = {Should governments use a declining discount rate in project
             analysis?},
   Journal = {Review of Environmental Economics and Policy},
   Volume = {8},
   Number = {2},
   Pages = {145-163},
   Publisher = {Oxford University Press (OUP)},
   Year = {2014},
   Month = {January},
   ISSN = {1750-6816},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/10268 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {At a workshop held at Resources for the Future in September
             2011, twelve of the authors were asked by the US
             Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) to provide advice on
             the principles to be used in discounting the benefits and
             costs of projects that affect future generations. Maureen L.
             Cropper chaired the workshop. Much of the discussion in this
             article is based on the authors' recommendations and advice
             presented at the workshop. © The Author
             2014.},
   Doi = {10.1093/reep/reu008},
   Key = {fds267094}
}

@article{fds267095,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Pizer, WA and Raimi, D},
   Title = {Carbon markets: Effective policy? - Response},
   Journal = {Science (New York, N.Y.)},
   Volume = {344},
   Number = {6191},
   Pages = {1460-1461},
   Year = {2014},
   Month = {January},
   ISSN = {0036-8075},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/10261 Duke open
             access},
   Doi = {10.1126/science.344.6191.1460-c},
   Key = {fds267095}
}

@article{fds267097,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Pizer, WA and Raimi, D},
   Title = {Carbon market lessons and global policy outlook},
   Journal = {Science (New York, N.Y.)},
   Volume = {343},
   Number = {6177},
   Pages = {1316-1317},
   Year = {2014},
   Month = {January},
   ISSN = {0036-8075},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/10260 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {Ongoing work on linking markets and mixing policies builds
             on successes and failures in pricing and trading
             carbon.},
   Doi = {10.1126/science.1246907},
   Key = {fds267097}
}

@article{fds267072,
   Author = {Arrow, KJ and Cropper, M and Gollier, C and Groom, B and Heal, GM and Newell, RG and Nordhaus, WD and Pindyck, RS and Pizer, WA and Portney,
             P and Sterner, T and Tol, RSJ and Weitzman, M},
   Title = {How Should Benefits and Costs Be Discounted in an
             Intergenerational Context? The Views of an Expert
             Panel},
   Year = {2013},
   Month = {December},
   Abstract = {In September 2011, the US Environmental Protection Agency
             asked 12 economists how the benefits and costs of
             regulations should be discounted for projects that affect
             future generations. This paper summarizes the views of the
             panel on three topics: the use of the Ramsey formula as an
             organizing principle for determining discount rates over
             long horizons, whether the discount rate should decline over
             time, and how intra- and intergenerational discounting
             practices can be made compatible. The panel members agree
             that the Ramsey formula provides a useful framework for
             thinking about intergenerational discounting. We also agree
             that theory provides compelling arguments for a declining
             certainty-equivalent discount rate. In the Ramsey formula,
             uncertainty about the future rate of growth in per capita
             consumption can lead to a declining consumption rate of
             discount, assuming that shocks to consumption are positively
             correlated. This uncertainty in future consumption growth
             rates may be estimated econometrically based on historic
             observations, or it can be derived from subjective
             uncertainty about the mean rate of growth in mean
             consumption or its volatility. Determining the remaining
             parameters of the Ramsey formula is, however,
             challenging.},
   Key = {fds267072}
}

@article{fds267113,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Pizer, WA and Raimi, D},
   Title = {Carbon markets 15 years after Kyoto: Lessons learned, new
             challenges},
   Journal = {The Journal of Economic Perspectives : a Journal of the
             American Economic Association},
   Volume = {27},
   Number = {1},
   Pages = {123-146},
   Publisher = {American Economic Association},
   Year = {2013},
   Month = {December},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/10264 Duke open
             access},
   Doi = {10.1257/jep.27.1.123},
   Key = {fds267113}
}

@article{fds267059,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Siikamäki, J},
   Title = {Nudging Energy Efficiency Behavior: The Role of Information
             Labels},
   Journal = {Resources for the Future Discussion Paper},
   Number = {13},
   Year = {2013},
   Month = {July},
   Abstract = {We evaluate the effectiveness of energy efficiency labeling
             in guiding household appliance choice decisions. Using a
             carefully designed choice experiment with several
             alternative labeling treatments, we disentangle the relative
             importance of different types of information and
             intertemporal behavior (i.e., discounting) in guiding energy
             efficiency behavior. We find that simple information on the
             economic value of saving energy was the most important
             element guiding more cost-efficient investments in appliance
             energy efficiency, with information on physical energy use
             and carbon dioxide emissions having additional but lesser
             importance. The degree to which the current EnergyGuide
             label guided cost-efficient decisions depends importantly on
             the discount rate assumed appropriate for the analysis.
             Using individual discount rates separately elicited in our
             study, we find that the current EnergyGuide label came very
             close to guiding cost-efficient decisions, on average.
             However, using a uniform five percent rate for discounting
             — which was much lower than the average individual
             elicited rate — the EnergyGuide label led to choices that
             result in a one-third undervaluation of energy efficiency.
             We find that labels that not only nudged people with
             dispassionate monetary or physical information, but also
             endorsed a model (with Energy Star) or gave a suggestive
             grade to a model (as with the EU-style label), had a
             substantial impact in encouraging the choice of appliances
             with higher energy efficiency. Our results reinforce the
             centrality of views on intertemporal choice and discounting,
             both in terms of understanding individual behavior and in
             guiding public policy decisions.},
   Key = {fds267059}
}

@article{fds267071,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Siikamäki, J},
   Title = {Nudging Energy Efficiency Behavior: The Role of Information
             Labels},
   Year = {2013},
   Month = {July},
   Abstract = {We evaluate the effectiveness of energy efficiency labeling
             in guiding household decisions. Using a carefully designed
             choice experiment with alternative labels, we disentangle
             the relative importance of different types of information
             and intertemporal behavior (i.e., discounting) in guiding
             energy efficiency behavior. We find that simple information
             on the economic value of saving energy was the most
             important element guiding more cost-efficient investments in
             energy efficiency, with information on physical energy use
             and carbon emissions having additional but lesser
             importance. The degree to which the current EnergyGuide
             label guided cost-efficient decisions depends importantly on
             the discount rate assumed. Using individual discount rates
             separately elicited in our study, we find that the current
             EnergyGuide label came very close to guiding cost-efficient
             decisions, on average. However, using a uniform five percent
             discount rate--which was much lower than the average
             elicited rate--the EnergyGuide label led to choices that
             result in a one-third undervaluation of energy efficiency.
             We find that labels that also endorsed a model (with Energy
             Star) or gave a suggestive grade to a model (EU-style
             label), encouraged substantially higher energy efficiency.
             Our results reinforce the centrality of views on
             intertemporal choice and discounting, both in terms of
             understanding individual behavior and in guiding
             policy.<br><br>Institutional subscribers to the NBER working
             paper series, and residents of developing countries may
             download this paper without additional charge at <a
             href="http://www.nber.org/papers/&#119??19224"
             TARGET="_blank">www.nber.org</a>.<br>},
   Key = {fds267071}
}

@article{fds267081,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Iler, S},
   Title = {The Global Energy Outlook},
   Year = {2013},
   Month = {April},
   Abstract = {We explore the principal trends that are shaping the future
             landscape of energy supply, demand, and trade. We take a
             long-term view, assessing trends on the time scale of a
             generation by looking 25 years into the past, taking stock
             of the current situation, and projecting 25 years into the
             future. We view these market, technology, and policy trends
             at a global scale, as well as assess the key regional
             dynamics that are substantially altering the energy scene.
             The shift from West to East in the locus of energy growth
             and the turnaround of North American gas and oil production
             are the most pronounced of these currents. Key uncertainties
             include the strength of economic and population growth in
             emerging economies, the stringency of future actions to
             reduce carbon emissions, the magnitude of unconventional
             natural gas and oil development in non-OPEC countries, and
             the stability of OPEC oil supplies.<br><br>Institutional
             subscribers to the NBER working paper series, and residents
             of developing countries may download this paper without
             additional charge at <a href="http://www.nber.org/papers/&#119??18967"
             TARGET="_blank">www.nber.org</a>.<br>},
   Key = {fds267081}
}

@article{fds267098,
   Author = {Arrow, K and Cropper, M and Gollier, C and Groom, B and Heal, G and Newell,
             R and Nordhaus, W and Pindyck, R and Pizer, W and Portney, P and Sterner,
             T and Tol, RSJ and Weitzman, M},
   Title = {Determining benefits and costs for future
             generations},
   Journal = {Science (New York, N.Y.)},
   Volume = {341},
   Number = {6144},
   Pages = {349-350},
   Year = {2013},
   Month = {January},
   ISSN = {0036-8075},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/10265 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {The United States and others should consider adopting a
             different approach to estimating costs and benefits in light
             of uncertainty.},
   Doi = {10.1126/science.1235665},
   Key = {fds267098}
}

@article{fds267055,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Pizer, WA and Raimi, D},
   Title = {Carbon Markets: Past, Present, and Future},
   Year = {2012},
   Month = {December},
   Abstract = {Carbon markets are substantial and they are expanding. There
             are many lessons from experiences over the past eight years:
             fewer free allowances, better management of market-sensitive
             information, and a recognition that trading systems require
             adjustments that have consequences for market participants
             and market confidence. Moreover, the emerging international
             architecture features separate emissions trading systems
             serving distinct jurisdictions. These programs are
             complemented by a variety of other types of policies
             alongside the carbon markets. This sits in sharp contrast to
             the integrated global trading architecture envisioned 15
             years ago by the designers of the Kyoto Protocol and raises
             a suite of new questions. In this new architecture,
             jurisdictions with emissions trading have to decide how,
             whether, and when to link with one another, and policymakers
             overseeing carbon markets must confront how to measure the
             comparability of efforts among markets and relative to a
             variety of other policy approaches.},
   Key = {fds267055}
}

@article{fds267121,
   Author = {Eccles, JK and Pratson, L and Newell, RG and Jackson,
             RB},
   Title = {The impact of geologic variability on capacity and cost
             estimates for storing CO 2 in deep-saline
             aquifers},
   Journal = {Energy Economics},
   Volume = {34},
   Number = {5},
   Pages = {1569-1579},
   Publisher = {Elsevier BV},
   Year = {2012},
   Month = {September},
   ISSN = {0140-9883},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/6609 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {While numerous studies find that deep-saline sandstone
             aquifers in the United States could store many decades worth
             of the nation's current annual CO 2 emissions, the likely
             cost of this storage (i.e. the cost of storage only and not
             capture and transport costs) has been harder to constrain.
             We use publicly available data of key reservoir properties
             to produce geo-referenced rasters of estimated storage
             capacity and cost for regions within 15 deep-saline
             sandstone aquifers in the United States. The rasters reveal
             the reservoir quality of these aquifers to be so variable
             that the cost estimates for storage span three orders of
             magnitude and average>$100/tonne CO 2. However, when the
             cost and corresponding capacity estimates in the rasters are
             assembled into a marginal abatement cost curve (MACC), we
             find that ~75% of the estimated storage capacity could be
             available for<$2/tonne. Furthermore, ~80% of the total
             estimated storage capacity in the rasters is concentrated
             within just two of the aquifers-the Frio Formation along the
             Texas Gulf Coast, and the Mt. Simon Formation in the
             Michigan Basin, which together make up only ~20% of the
             areas analyzed. While our assessment is not comprehensive,
             the results suggest there should be an abundance of low-cost
             storage for CO 2 in deep-saline aquifers, but a majority of
             this storage is likely to be concentrated within specific
             regions of a smaller number of these aquifers. © 2011
             Elsevier B.V.},
   Doi = {10.1016/j.eneco.2011.11.015},
   Key = {fds267121}
}

@article{fds267112,
   Author = {Arimura, TH and Li, S and Newell, RG and Palmer, K},
   Title = {Cost-effectiveness of electricity energy efficiency
             programs},
   Journal = {The Energy Journal},
   Volume = {33},
   Number = {2},
   Pages = {63-99},
   Publisher = {International Association for Energy Economics
             (IAEE)},
   Year = {2012},
   Month = {August},
   ISSN = {0195-6574},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/7010 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {We analyze the cost-effectiveness of electric utility
             ratepayer-funded programs to promote demand-side management
             (DSM) and energy efficiency (EE) investments. We specify a
             model that relates electricity demand to previous EE DSM
             spending, energy prices, income, weather, and other demand
             factors. In contrast to previous studies, we allow EE DSM
             spending to have a potential longterm demand effect and
             explicitly address possible endogeneity in spending. We find
             that current period EE DSM expenditures reduce electricity
             demand and that this effect persists for a number of years.
             Our findings suggest that ratepayer funded DSM expenditures
             between 1992 and 2006 produced a central estimate of 0.9
             percent savings in electricity consumption over that time
             period and a 1.8 percent savings over all years. These
             energy savings came at an expected average cost to utilities
             of roughly 5 cents per kWh saved when future savings are
             discounted at a 5 percent rate. Copyright © 2012 by the
             IAEE. All rights reserved.},
   Doi = {10.5547/01956574.33.2.4},
   Key = {fds267112}
}

@article{fds267120,
   Author = {Popp, D and Newell, R},
   Title = {Where does energy R&D come from? Examining crowding out
             from energy R&D},
   Journal = {Energy Economics},
   Volume = {34},
   Number = {4},
   Pages = {980-991},
   Publisher = {Elsevier BV},
   Year = {2012},
   Month = {July},
   ISSN = {0140-9883},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/6758 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {Recent efforts to endogenize technological change in climate
             policy models demonstrate the importance of accounting for
             the opportunity cost of climate R&D investments. Because the
             social returns to R&D investments are typically higher than
             the social returns to other types of investment, any new
             climate mitigation R&D that comes at the expense of other
             R&D investment may dampen the overall gains from induced
             technological change. Unfortunately, there has been little
             empirical work to guide modelers as to the potential
             magnitude of such crowding out effects. This paper considers
             both the private and social opportunity costs of climate
             R&D. Addressing private costs, we ask whether an increase in
             climate R&D represents new R&D spending, or whether some (or
             all) of the additional climate R&D comes at the expense of
             other R&D. Addressing social costs, we use patent citations
             to compare the social value of alternative energy research
             to other types of R&D that may be crowded out. Beginning at
             the industry level, we find no evidence of crowding out
             across sectors-that is, increases in energy R&D do not draw
             R&D resources away from sectors that do not perform R&D.
             Given this, we proceed with a detailed look at alternative
             energy R&D. Linking patent data and financial data by firm,
             we ask whether an increase in alternative energy patents
             leads to a decrease in other types of patenting activity.
             While we find that increases in alternative energy patents
             do result in fewer patents of other types, the evidence
             suggests that this is due to profit-maximizing changes in
             research effort, rather than financial constraints that
             limit the total amount of R&D possible. Finally, we use
             patent citation data to compare the social value of
             alternative energy patents to other patents by these firms.
             Alternative energy patents are cited more frequently, and by
             a wider range of other technologies, than other patents by
             these firms, suggesting that their social value is higher.
             © 2011 Elsevier B.V.},
   Doi = {10.1016/j.eneco.2011.07.001},
   Key = {fds267120}
}

@article{fds289608,
   Author = {Arimura, TH and Li, S and Newell, RG and Palmer, K},
   Title = {Cost-Effectiveness of Electricity Energy Efficiency
             Programs},
   Year = {2011},
   Month = {April},
   Abstract = {We analyze the cost-effectiveness of electric utility
             ratepayer-funded programs to promote demand-side management
             (DSM) and energy efficiency (EE) investments. We specify a
             model that relates electricity demand to previous EE DSM
             spending, energy prices, income, weather, and other demand
             factors. In contrast to previous studies, we allow EE DSM
             spending to have a potential long-term demand effect and
             explicitly address possible endogeneity in spending. We find
             that current period EE DSM expenditures reduce electricity
             demand and that this effect persists for a number of years.
             Our findings suggest that ratepayer-funded DSM expenditures
             between 1992 and 2006 produced a central estimate of 0.9
             percent savings in electricity consumption over that time
             period and 1.8 percent savings over all years. These energy
             savings came at an expected average cost to utilities of
             roughly 5 cents per kWh saved when future savings are
             discounted at a 5 percent rate.},
   Key = {fds289608}
}

@article{fds289609,
   Author = {Arimura, TH and Li, S and Newell, RG and Palmer, KL},
   Title = {Cost-Effectiveness of Electricity Energy Efficiency
             Programs},
   Year = {2011},
   Month = {April},
   Abstract = {We analyze the cost-effectiveness of electric utility
             ratepayer-funded programs to promote demand-side management
             (DSM) and energy efficiency (EE) investments. We specify a
             model that relates electricity demand to previous EE DSM
             spending, energy prices, income, weather, and other demand
             factors. In contrast to previous studies, we allow EE DSM
             spending to have a potential long-term demand effect and
             explicitly address possible endogeneity in spending. We find
             that current period EE DSM expenditures reduce electricity
             demand and that this effect persists for a number of years.
             Our findings suggest that ratepayer-funded DSM expenditures
             between 1992 and 2006 produced a central estimate of 0.9
             percent savings in electricity consumption over that time
             period and 1.8 percent savings over all years. These energy
             savings came at an expected average cost to utilities of
             roughly 5 cents per kWh saved when future savings are
             discounted at a 5 percent rate.},
   Key = {fds289609}
}

@article{fds267118,
   Author = {Aldy, JE and Krupnick, AJ and Newell, RG and Parry, IWH and Pizer,
             WA},
   Title = {Designing climate mitigation policy},
   Journal = {Journal of Economic Literature},
   Volume = {48},
   Number = {4},
   Pages = {903-934},
   Publisher = {American Economic Association},
   Year = {2010},
   Month = {December},
   ISSN = {0022-0515},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/7011 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {This paper provides (for the nonspecialist) a highly
             streamlined discussion of the main issues, and
             controversies, in the design of climate mitigation policy.
             The first part of the paper discusses how much action to
             reduce greenhouse gas emissions at the global level is
             efficient under both the cost-effectiveness and
             welfare-maximizing paradigms. We then discuss various issues
             in the implementation of domestic emissions control policy,
             instrument choice, and incentives for technological
             innovation. Finally, we discuss alternative policy
             architectures at the international level.},
   Doi = {10.1257/jel.48.4.903},
   Key = {fds267118}
}

@article{fds343297,
   Author = {Aldy, JE and Krupnick, AJ and Newell, RG and Parry, IWH and Pizer,
             WA},
   Title = {Designing Climate Mitigation Policy},
   Year = {2010},
   Month = {December},
   Abstract = {This paper provides (for the nonspecialist) a highly
             streamlined discussion of the main issues, and
             controversies, in the design of climate mitigation policy.
             The first part of the paper discusses how much action to
             reduce greenhouse gas emissions at the global level is
             efficient under both the cost-effectiveness and
             welfare-maximizing paradigms. We then discuss various issues
             in the implementation of domestic emissions control policy,
             instrument choice, and incentives for technological
             innovation. Finally, we discuss alternative policy
             architectures at the international level. (JEL Q54,
             Q58)},
   Key = {fds343297}
}

@article{fds267119,
   Author = {Newell, RG},
   Title = {The role of markets and policies in delivering innovation
             for climate change mitigation},
   Journal = {Oxford Review of Economic Policy},
   Volume = {26},
   Number = {2},
   Pages = {253-269},
   Publisher = {Oxford University Press (OUP)},
   Year = {2010},
   Month = {June},
   ISSN = {0266-903X},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/6751 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {This paper identifies market incentives and international
             and domestic policies that could technologically alter
             energy systems to achieve greenhouse gas stabilization
             targets while also meeting other societal goals. I consider
             the conceptual basis and empirical evidence on the
             effectiveness and efficiency of climate technology policies.
             The paper reviews the literature on trends and prospects for
             innovation in climate change mitigation and examines the
             evidence on induced innovation and the implications for the
             choice of technology policy. I then consider the impact of
             technological advances on the environment, the role of
             direct government support for R&D, and the complementarities
             between policies internalizing environmental externalities
             and those aimed at environmental innovations. © The Author
             2010. Published by Oxford University Press.},
   Doi = {10.1093/oxrep/grq009},
   Key = {fds267119}
}

@article{fds267111,
   Author = {Popp, D and Newell, RG and Jaffe, AB},
   Title = {Energy, the environment, and technological
             change},
   Journal = {Handbook of the Economics of Innovation},
   Volume = {2},
   Number = {1},
   Pages = {873-937},
   Booktitle = {Handbook of Economics of Technical Change.},
   Publisher = {Elsevier},
   Year = {2010},
   Month = {January},
   ISSN = {2210-8807},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/7460 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {Within the field of environmental economics, the role of
             technological change has received much attention. The
             long-term nature of many environmental problems, such as
             climate change, makes understanding the evolution of
             technology an important part of projecting future impacts.
             Moreover, in many cases, environmental problems cannot be
             addressed, or can only be addressed at great cost, using
             existing technologies. Providing incentives to develop new
             environmentally friendly technologies then becomes a focus
             of environmental policy. This chapter reviews the literature
             on technological change and the environment. Our goals are
             to introduce technological change economists to how the
             lessons of the economics of technological change have been
             applied in the field of environmental economics, and suggest
             ways in which scholars of technological change could
             contribute to the field of environmental economics. © 2010
             Elsevier B.V.},
   Doi = {10.1016/S0169-7218(10)02005-8},
   Key = {fds267111}
}

@article{fds267087,
   Author = {Popp, D and Newell, RG},
   Title = {Where Does Energy R&D Come from? Examining Crowding Out from
             Environmentally-Friendly R&D},
   Year = {2009},
   Month = {October},
   Abstract = {Recent efforts to endogenize technological change in climate
             policy models demonstrate the importance of accounting for
             the opportunity cost of climate R&D investments. Because the
             social returns to R&D investments are typically higher than
             the social returns to other types of investment, any new
             climate mitigation R&D that comes at the expense of other
             R&D investment may dampen the overall gains from induced
             technological change. Unfortunately, there has been little
             empirical work to guide modelers as to the potential
             magnitude of such crowding out effects. This paper considers
             both the private and social opportunity costs of climate
             R&D. Addressing private costs, we ask whether an increase in
             climate R&D represents new R&D spending, or whether some (or
             all) of the additional climate R&D comes at the expense of
             other R&D. Addressing social costs, we use patent citations
             to compare the social value of alternative energy research
             to other types of R&D that may be crowded out. Beginning at
             the industry level, we find some evidence of crowding out in
             sectors active in energy R&D, but not in sectors that do not
             perform energy R&D. This suggests that funds for energy R&D
             do not come from other sectors, but may come from a
             redistribution of research funds in sectors that are likely
             to perform energy R&D. Given this, we proceed with a
             detailed look at climate R&D in two sectors - alternative
             energy and automotive manufacturing. Linking patent data and
             financial data by firm, we ask whether an increase in
             alternative energy patents leads to a decrease in other
             types of patenting activity. We find crowding out for
             alternative energy firms, but no evidence of crowding out
             for automotive firms. Finally, we use patent citation data
             to compare the social value of alternative energy patents to
             other patents by these firms. Alternative energy patents are
             cited more frequently, and by a wider range of other
             technologies, than other patents by these firms, suggesting
             that their social value is higher.},
   Key = {fds267087}
}

@article{fds365724,
   Author = {Bennear, LS and Olmstead, SM},
   Title = {Information Disclosure and Drinking Water
             Quality},
   Journal = {Resources Magazine},
   Year = {2009},
   Month = {October},
   Key = {fds365724}
}

@article{fds289607,
   Author = {Aldy, JE and Krupnick, A and Newell, RG and Parry, IWH and Pizer,
             WA},
   Title = {Designing Climate Mitigation Policy},
   Year = {2009},
   Month = {June},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/7011 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {This paper provides an exhaustive review of critical issues
             in the design of climate mitigation policy by pulling
             together key findings and controversies from diverse
             literatures on mitigation costs, damage valuation, policy
             instrument choice, technological innovation, and
             international climate policy. We begin with the broadest
             issue of how high assessments suggest the near and medium
             term price on greenhouse gases would need to be, both under
             cost-effective stabilization of global climate and under net
             benefit maximization or Pigouvian emissions pricing. The
             remainder of the paper focuses on the appropriate scope of
             regulation, issues in policy instrument choice,
             complementary technology policy, and international policy
             architectures.},
   Key = {fds289607}
}

@article{fds338094,
   Author = {Gillingham, K and Newell, RG and Palmer, KL},
   Title = {Energy Efficiency Economics and Policy},
   Year = {2009},
   Month = {June},
   Key = {fds338094}
}

@article{fds290514,
   Author = {Gillingham, K and Newell, RG and Palmer, KL},
   Title = {Energy Efficiency Economics and Policy},
   Year = {2009},
   Month = {April},
   Abstract = {Energy efficiency and conservation are considered key means
             for reducing greenhouse gas emissions and achieving other
             energy policy goals, but associated market behavior and
             policy responses have engendered debates in the economic
             literature. We review economic concepts underlying consumer
             decisionmaking in energy efficiency and conservation and
             examine related empirical literature. In particular, we
             provide an economic perspective on the range of market
             barriers, market failures, and behavioral failures that have
             been cited in the energy efficiency context. We assess the
             extent to which these conditions provide a motivation for
             policy intervention in energy-using product markets,
             including an examination of the evidence on policy
             effectiveness and cost. While theory and empirical evidence
             suggest there is potential for welfare-enhancing energy
             efficiency policies, many open questions remain,
             particularly relating to the extent of some of the key
             market and behavioral failures.},
   Key = {fds290514}
}

@article{fds267126,
   Author = {Eccles, JK and Pratson, L and Newell, RG and Jackson,
             RB},
   Title = {Physical and economic potential of geological CO
             2 storage in saline aquifers},
   Journal = {Environmental Science & Technology},
   Volume = {43},
   Number = {6},
   Pages = {1962-1969},
   Year = {2009},
   Month = {March},
   ISSN = {0013-936X},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/6611 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {Carbon sequestration in sandstone saline reservoirs holds
             great potential for mitigating climate change, but its
             storage potential and cost per ton of avoided CO 2 emissions
             are uncertain. We develop a general model to determine the
             maximum theoretical constraints on both storage potential
             and injection rate and use it to characterize the economic
             viability of geosequestration in sandstone saline aquifers.
             When applied to a representative set of aquifer
             characteristics, the model yields results that compare
             favorably with pilot projects currently underway. Over a
             range of reservoir properties, maximum effective storage
             peaks at an optimal depth of 1600 m, at which point
             0.18-0.31 metric tons can be stored per cubic meter of bulk
             volume of reservoir. Maximum modeled injection rates predict
             minima for storage costs in a typical basin in the range of
             $2-7/ ton CO 2(2005 U.S. $) depending on depth and basin
             characteristics in our base-case scenario. Because the
             properties of natural reservoirs in the United States vary
             substantially, storage costs could in some cases be lower or
             higher by orders of magnitude. We conclude that available
             geosequestration capacity exhibits a wide range of
             technological and economic attractiveness. Like traditional
             projects in the extractive industries, geosequestration
             capacity should be exploited starting with the low-cost
             storage options first then moving gradually up the supply
             curve. © 2009 American Chemical Society.},
   Doi = {10.1021/es801572e},
   Key = {fds267126}
}

@article{fds267125,
   Author = {Murray, BC and Newell, RG and Pizer, WA},
   Title = {Balancing cost and emissions certainty: An allowance reserve
             for cap-and-trade},
   Journal = {Review of Environmental Economics and Policy},
   Volume = {3},
   Number = {1},
   Pages = {84-103},
   Publisher = {Oxford University Press (OUP)},
   Year = {2009},
   Month = {Winter},
   ISSN = {1750-6816},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/6750 Duke open
             access},
   Doi = {10.1093/reep/ren016},
   Key = {fds267125}
}

@article{fds267124,
   Author = {Gillingham, K and Newell, RG and Palmer, K},
   Title = {Energy Efficiency Economics and Policy},
   Journal = {Annual Review of Resource Economics},
   Volume = {1},
   Number = {1},
   Pages = {597-619},
   Publisher = {ANNUAL REVIEWS},
   Year = {2009},
   ISSN = {1941-1340},
   url = {http://gateway.webofknowledge.com/gateway/Gateway.cgi?GWVersion=2&SrcApp=PARTNER_APP&SrcAuth=LinksAMR&KeyUT=WOS:000273629900027&DestLinkType=FullRecord&DestApp=ALL_WOS&UsrCustomerID=47d3190e77e5a3a53558812f597b0b92},
   Abstract = {Energy efficiency and conservation are considered key means
             for reducing greenhouse gas emissions and achieving other
             energy policy goals, but associated market behavior and
             policy responses have engendered debates in the economic
             literature. We review economic concepts underlying consumer
             decision making in energy efficiency and conservation and
             examine related empirical literature. In particular, we
             provide an economic perspective on the range of market
             barriers, market failures, and behavioral failures that have
             been cited in the energy efficiency context. We assess the
             extent to which these conditions provide a motivation for
             policy intervention in energy-using product markets,
             including an examination of the evidence on policy
             effectiveness and cost. Although theory and empirical
             evidence suggests there is potential for welfare-enhancing
             energy efficiency policies, many open questions remain,
             particularly relating to the extent of some key market and
             behavioral failures.},
   Doi = {10.1146/annurev.resource.102308.124234},
   Key = {fds267124}
}

@article{fds267127,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Pizer, WA},
   Title = {Carbon mitigation costs for the commercial building sector:
             Discrete-continuous choice analysis of multifuel energy
             demand},
   Journal = {Resource and Energy Economics},
   Volume = {30},
   Number = {4},
   Pages = {527-539},
   Publisher = {Elsevier BV},
   Year = {2008},
   Month = {December},
   ISSN = {0928-7655},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/7456 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {We estimate a carbon mitigation cost curve for the U.S.
             commercial sector based on econometric estimation of the
             responsiveness of fuel demand and equipment choices to
             energy price changes. The model econometrically estimates
             fuel demand conditional on fuel choice, which is
             characterized by a multinomial logit model. Separate
             estimation of end uses (e.g., heating, cooking) using the
             U.S. Commercial Buildings Energy Consumption Survey allows
             for exceptionally detailed estimation of price
             responsiveness disaggregated by end use and fuel type. We
             then construct aggregate long-run elasticities, by fuel
             type, through a series of simulations; own-price
             elasticities range from -0.9 for district heat services to
             -2.9 for fuel oil. The simulations form the basis of a
             marginal cost curve for carbon mitigation, which suggests
             that a price of $20 per ton of carbon would result in an 8%
             reduction in commercial carbon emissions, and a price of
             $100 per ton would result in a 28% reduction. © 2008
             Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.},
   Doi = {10.1016/j.reseneeco.2008.09.004},
   Key = {fds267127}
}

@article{fds267123,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Pizer, WA},
   Title = {Indexed regulation},
   Journal = {Journal of Environmental Economics and Management},
   Volume = {56},
   Number = {3},
   Pages = {221-233},
   Publisher = {Elsevier BV},
   Year = {2008},
   Month = {November},
   ISSN = {0095-0696},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/6755 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {Seminal work by Weitzman [Prices vs. quantities, Rev. Econ.
             Stud. 41 (1974) 477-491] revealed prices are preferred to
             quantities when marginal benefits are relatively flat
             compared to marginal costs. We extend this comparison to
             indexed policies, where quantities are proportional to an
             index, such as output. We find that policy preferences hinge
             on additional parameters describing the first and second
             moments of the index and the ex post optimal quantity level.
             When the ratio of these variables' coefficients of variation
             divided by their correlation is less than approximately two,
             indexed quantities are preferred to fixed quantities. A
             slightly more complex condition determines when indexed
             quantities are preferred to prices. Applied to climate
             change policy, we find that the range of variation and
             correlation in country-level carbon dioxide emissions and
             GDP suggests the ranking of an emissions intensity cap
             (indexed to GDP) compared to a fixed emission cap is not
             uniform across countries; neither policy clearly dominates
             the other. © 2008 Elsevier Inc. All rights
             reserved.},
   Doi = {10.1016/j.jeem.2008.07.001},
   Key = {fds267123}
}

@article{fds267128,
   Author = {Gillingham, K and Newell, RG and Pizer, WA},
   Title = {Modeling endogenous technological change for climate policy
             analysis},
   Journal = {Energy Economics},
   Volume = {30},
   Number = {6},
   Pages = {2734-2753},
   Publisher = {Elsevier BV},
   Year = {2008},
   Month = {November},
   ISSN = {0140-9883},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/6628 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {The approach used to model technological change in a climate
             policy model is a critical determinant of its results in
             terms of the time path of CO2 prices and costs required to
             achieve various emission reduction goals. We provide an
             overview of the different approaches used in the literature,
             with an emphasis on recent developments regarding endogenous
             technological change, research and development, and
             learning. Detailed examination sheds light on the salient
             features of each approach, including strengths, limitations,
             and policy implications. Key issues include proper
             accounting for the opportunity costs of climate-related
             knowledge generation, treatment of knowledge spillovers and
             appropriability, and the empirical basis for parameterizing
             technological relationships. No single approach appears to
             dominate on all these dimensions, and different approaches
             may be preferred depending on the purpose of the analysis,
             be it positive or normative. © 2008 Elsevier B.V. All
             rights reserved.},
   Doi = {10.1016/j.eneco.2008.03.001},
   Key = {fds267128}
}

@article{fds267060,
   Author = {Murray, BC and Newell, RG and Pizer, WA},
   Title = {Balancing Cost and Emissions Certainty: An Allowance Reserve
             for Cap-and-Trade},
   Year = {2008},
   Month = {July},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/6750 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {On efficiency grounds, the economics community has to date
             tended to emphasize price-based policies to address climate
             change -- such as taxes or a “safety-valve” price
             ceiling for cap-and-trade -— while environmental advocates
             have sought a more clear quantitative limit on emissions.
             This paper presents a simple modification to the idea of a
             safety valve -- a quantitative limit that we call the
             allowance reserve. Importantly, this idea may bridge the gap
             between competing interests and potentially improve
             efficiency relative to tax or other price-based policies.
             The last point highlights the deficiencies in several
             previous studies of price and quantity controls for climate
             change that do not adequately capture the dynamic
             opportunities within a cap-and-trade system for allowance
             banking, borrowing, and intertemporal arbitrage in response
             to unfolding information.},
   Key = {fds267060}
}

@article{fds267130,
   Author = {Fischer, C and Newell, RG},
   Title = {Environmental and technology policies for climate
             mitigation},
   Journal = {Journal of Environmental Economics and Management},
   Volume = {55},
   Number = {2},
   Pages = {142-162},
   Publisher = {Elsevier BV},
   Year = {2008},
   Month = {March},
   ISSN = {0095-0696},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/6623 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {We assess different policies for reducing carbon dioxide
             emissions and promoting innovation and diffusion of
             renewable energy. We evaluate the relative performance of
             policies according to incentives provided for emissions
             reduction, efficiency, and other outcomes. We also assess
             how the nature of technological progress through learning
             and research and development (R&D), and the degree of
             knowledge spillovers, affects the desirability of different
             policies. Due to knowledge spillovers, optimal policy
             involves a portfolio of different instruments targeted at
             emissions, learning, and R&D. Although the relative cost of
             individual policies in achieving reductions depends on
             parameter values and the emissions target, in a numerical
             application to the U.S. electricity sector, the ranking is
             roughly as follows: (1) emissions price, (2) emissions
             performance standard, (3) fossil power tax, (4) renewables
             share requirement, (5) renewables subsidy, and (6) R&D
             subsidy. Nonetheless, an optimal portfolio of policies
             achieves emissions reductions at a significantly lower cost
             than any single policy. © 2007 Elsevier Inc. All rights
             reserved.},
   Doi = {10.1016/j.jeem.2007.11.001},
   Key = {fds267130}
}

@article{fds267133,
   Author = {de Coninck, H and Fischer, C and Newell, RG and Ueno,
             T},
   Title = {International technology-oriented agreements to address
             climate change},
   Journal = {Energy Policy},
   Volume = {36},
   Number = {1},
   Pages = {335-356},
   Publisher = {Elsevier BV},
   Year = {2008},
   Month = {January},
   ISSN = {0301-4215},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/6760 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {Much discussion has surrounded possible alternatives for
             international agreements on climate change, particularly
             post-2012. Among these alternatives, technology-oriented
             agreements (TOAs) are perhaps the least well defined. We
             explore what TOAs may consist of, why they might be
             sensible, which TOAs already exist in international energy
             and environmental governance, and whether they could make a
             valuable contribution to addressing climate change. We find
             that TOAs aimed at knowledge sharing and coordination,
             research, development, or demonstration could increase the
             overall efficiency and effectiveness of international
             climate cooperation, but are likely to have limited
             environmental effectiveness on their own.
             Technology-transfer agreements are likely to have similar
             properties unless the level of resources expended is large,
             in which case they could be environmentally significant.
             Technology-specific mandates or incentives could be
             environmentally effective within the applicable sector, but
             are more likely to make a cost-effective contribution when
             viewed as a complement to rather than a substitute for
             flexible emissions-based policies. These results indicate
             that TOAs could potentially provide a valuable contribution
             to the global response to climate change. The success of
             specific TOAs will depend on their design, implementation,
             and the role they are expected to play relative to other
             components of the policy portfolio. © 2007 Elsevier Ltd.
             All rights reserved.},
   Doi = {10.1016/j.enpol.2007.09.030},
   Key = {fds267133}
}

@article{fds195191,
   Author = {R.G. Newell and W.A. Pizer},
   Title = {Indexed Regulation},
   Journal = {J. Environ. Econ. and Management},
   Year = {2008},
   Key = {fds195191}
}

@article{fds267107,
   Author = {Fischer, C and Newell, R},
   Title = {What’s the Best way to Promote Green Power?: Don’t
             Forget the Emissions Price},
   Volume = {160},
   Pages = {10-13},
   Year = {2008},
   Month = {Summer},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/7393 Duke open
             access},
   Key = {fds267107}
}

@article{fds267117,
   Author = {Newell, R},
   Title = {What's the big deal about oil? How we can get oil policy
             right},
   Journal = {Current},
   Number = {494},
   Pages = {3-6},
   Year = {2007},
   Month = {July},
   ISSN = {0011-3131},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/6752 Duke open
             access},
   Key = {fds267117}
}

@article{fds267146,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Papps, KL and Sanchirico, JN},
   Title = {Asset pricing in created markets},
   Journal = {American Journal of Agricultural Economics},
   Volume = {89},
   Number = {2},
   Pages = {259-272},
   Publisher = {Oxford University Press (OUP)},
   Year = {2007},
   Month = {May},
   ISSN = {0002-9092},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/6753 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {We investigate the applicability of the present-value asset
             pricing model to fishing quota markets by applying
             instrumental variable panel data estimation techniques to 15
             years of market transactions from New Zealand's individual
             transferable quota (ITQ) market. In addition to the
             influence of current fishing rents, we explore the effect of
             market interest rates, risk, and expected changes in future
             rents on quota asset prices. The results indicate that quota
             asset prices are positively related to declines in interest
             rates, lower levels of risk, expected increases in future
             fish prices, and expected cost reductions from
             rationalization under the quota system. © 2007 American
             Agricultural Economics Association.},
   Doi = {10.1111/j.1467-8276.2007.01018.x},
   Key = {fds267146}
}

@article{fds267145,
   Author = {Gillingham, K and Newell, R and Palmer, K},
   Title = {Energy efficiency policies: A retrospective
             examination},
   Journal = {Annual Review of Environment and Resources},
   Volume = {31},
   Number = {1},
   Pages = {161-192},
   Publisher = {ANNUAL REVIEWS},
   Year = {2006},
   Month = {November},
   ISSN = {1543-5938},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/10269 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {We review literature on several types of energy efficiency
             policies: appliance standards, financial incentive programs,
             information and voluntary programs, and management of
             government energy use. For each, we provide a brief synopsis
             of the relevant programs, along with available existing
             estimates of energy savings, costs, and cost-effectiveness
             at a national level. The literature examining these
             estimates points to potential issues in determining the
             energy savings and costs, but recent evidence suggests that
             techniques for measuring both have improved. Taken together,
             the literature identifies up to four quads of energy savings
             annually from these programs - at least half of which is
             attributable to appliance standards and utility-based
             demand-side management, with possible additional energy
             savings from the U.S. Department of Energy's (DOE's) ENERGY
             STAR, Climate Challenge, and Section 1605b voluntary
             programs to reduce carbon dioxide (CO 2) emissions. Related
             reductions in CO 2 and criteria air pollutants may
             contribute an additional 10% to the value of energy savings
             above the price of energy itself. Copyright © 2006 by
             Annual Reviews. All rights reserved.},
   Doi = {10.1146/annurev.energy.31.020105.100157},
   Key = {fds267145}
}

@article{fds267116,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Jaffe, AB and Stavins, RN},
   Title = {The effects of economic and policy incentives on carbon
             mitigation technologies},
   Journal = {Energy Economics},
   Volume = {28},
   Number = {5-6},
   Pages = {563-578},
   Publisher = {Elsevier BV},
   Year = {2006},
   Month = {November},
   ISSN = {0140-9883},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2006.07.004},
   Abstract = {The ability to estimate the likely effects of potential
             climate change policies on energy use and greenhouse gas
             (GHG) emissions requires an improved understanding of the
             relationship between different policy alternatives and
             energy-saving and GHG-reducing changes in technology. A
             particularly important and understudied aspect of this set
             of issues is the conceptual and empirical modeling of how
             the various stages of technological change are interrelated,
             how they unfold over time in response to market forces, and
             the differential impact of various policies (for example,
             R&D subsidies, environmental taxes, information programs).
             We summarize several contributions to this literature and
             suggest promising areas for continued research on empirical
             analysis and modeling of induced technological change. ©
             2006 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.},
   Doi = {10.1016/j.eneco.2006.07.004},
   Key = {fds267116}
}

@article{fds267144,
   Author = {Pizer, W and Burtraw, D and Harrington, W and Newell, R and Sanchirico,
             J},
   Title = {Modeling economy-wide vs sectoral climate policies using
             combined aggregate-sectoral models},
   Journal = {The Energy Journal},
   Volume = {27},
   Number = {3},
   Pages = {135-168},
   Publisher = {International Association for Energy Economics
             (IAEE)},
   Year = {2006},
   Month = {January},
   ISSN = {0195-6574},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/10266 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {Economic analyses of climate change policies frequently
             focus on reductions of energy-related carbon dioxide
             emissions via market-based, economy-wide policies. The
             current course of environment and energy policy debate in
             the United States, however, suggests an alternative outcome:
             sector-based and/or inefficiently designed policies. This
             paper uses a collection of specialized, sector-based models
             in conjunction with a computable general equilibrium model
             of the economy to examine and compare these policies at an
             aggregate level. We examine the relative cost of different
             policies designed to achieve the same quantity of emission
             reductions. We find that excluding a limited number of
             sectors from an economy-wide policy does not significantly
             raise costs. Focusing policy solely on the electricity and
             transportation sectors doubles costs, however, and using
             non-market policies can raise cost by a factor of ten. These
             results are driven in part by, and are sensitive to, our
             modeling of pre-existing tax distortions. Copyright © 2006
             by the IAEE. All rights reserved.},
   Doi = {10.5547/ISSN0195-6574-EJ-Vol27-No3-8},
   Key = {fds267144}
}

@article{fds346828,
   Author = {Pizer, WA},
   Title = {Setting energy policy in the modern era: Tough challenges
             lie ahead},
   Journal = {The Rff Reader in Environmental and Resource Policy: Second
             Edition},
   Pages = {171-174},
   Year = {2006},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.4324/9781936331642},
   Doi = {10.4324/9781936331642},
   Key = {fds346828}
}

@article{fds267070,
   Author = {Sanchirico, J and Newell, R and Papps, K},
   Title = {Asset Pricing in Created Markets for Fishing
             Quotas},
   Year = {2005},
   Month = {October},
   Abstract = {We investigate the applicability of the present-value asset
             pricing model to fishing quota markets by applying
             instrumental variable panel data estimation techniques to 15
             years of market transactions from New Zealand’s individual
             fishing quota market. In addition to the influence of
             current fishing rents (as measured by lease prices), we
             explore the effect of market interest rates, risk, and
             expected changes in future rents on quota asset prices.
             Controlling for these other factors, the results support a
             fairly simple relationship between quota asset and
             contemporaneous lease prices. Consistent with theoretical
             expectations, the results indicate that quota asset prices
             are positively related to declines in interest rates, lower
             levels of risk, expected increases in future fish prices,
             and expected cost reductions from rationalization under the
             quota system. However, the magnitude of some
             interrelationships is muted relative to what theory
             suggests, possibly due to measurement error.},
   Key = {fds267070}
}

@article{fds267132,
   Author = {Jaffe, AB and Newell, RG and Stavins, RN},
   Title = {A tale of two market failures: Technology and environmental
             policy},
   Journal = {Ecological Economics},
   Volume = {54},
   Number = {2-3},
   Pages = {164-174},
   Publisher = {Elsevier BV},
   Year = {2005},
   Month = {August},
   ISSN = {0921-8009},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/10267 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {Market failures associated with environmental pollution
             interact with market failures associated with the innovation
             and diffusion of new technologies. These combined market
             failures provide a strong rationale for a portfolio of
             public policies that foster emissions reduction as well as
             the development and adoption of environmentally beneficial
             technology. Both theory and empirical evidence suggest that
             the rate and direction of technological advance is
             influenced by market and regulatory incentives, and can be
             cost-effectively harnessed through the use of
             economic-incentive based policy. In the presence of weak or
             nonexistent environmental policies, investments in the
             development and diffusion of new environmentally beneficial
             technologies are very likely to be less than would be
             socially desirable. Positive knowledge and adoption
             spillovers and information problems can further weaken
             innovation incentives. While environmental technology policy
             is fraught with difficulties, a long-term view suggests a
             strategy of experimenting with policy approaches and
             systematically evaluating their success. © 2005 Elsevier
             B.V. All rights reserved.},
   Doi = {10.1016/j.ecolecon.2004.12.027},
   Key = {fds267132}
}

@article{fds267068,
   Author = {Newell, R and Wilson, N},
   Title = {Technology Prizes for Climate Change Mitigation},
   Year = {2005},
   Month = {June},
   Abstract = {We analyze whether technology inducement prizes could be a
             useful complement to standard research grants and contracts
             in developing climate change mitigation technologies. We
             find that there are important conceptual advantages to using
             inducement prizes in certain circumstances. These conceptual
             inferences are borne out by an examination of the track
             record of prizes inducing research into public goods,
             including relevant energy technologies. However, we also
             find that the prizes’ successes are contingent on their
             proper design. We analyze how several important design
             elements could influence the effectiveness of a climate
             technology prize.},
   Key = {fds267068}
}

@article{fds267067,
   Author = {Pizer, W and Newell, R},
   Title = {Carbon Mitigation Costs for the Commercial Sector:
             Discrete-Continuous Choice Analysis of Multifuel Energy
             Demand},
   Year = {2005},
   Month = {June},
   Abstract = {We estimate a carbon mitigation cost curve for the U.S.
             commercial sector based on econometric estimation of the
             responsiveness of fuel demand and equipment choices to
             energy price changes. The model econometrically estimates
             fuel demand conditional on fuel choice, which is
             characterized by a multinomial logit model. Separate
             estimation of end uses (e.g., heating, cooking) using the
             1995 Commercial Buildings Energy Consumption Survey allows
             for exceptionally detailed estimation of price
             responsiveness disaggregated by end use and fuel type. We
             then construct aggregate long-run elasticities, by fuel
             type, through a series of simulations; own-price
             elasticities range from ?0.9 for district heat services to
             ?2.9 for fuel oil. The simulations form the basis of a
             marginal cost curve for carbon mitigation, which suggests
             that a price of $20 per ton of carbon would result in an 8%
             reduction in commercial carbon emissions, and a price of
             $100 per ton would result in a 28% reduction.},
   Key = {fds267067}
}

@article{fds267143,
   Author = {Newell, R and Pizer, W and Zhang, J},
   Title = {Managing permit markets to stabilize prices},
   Journal = {Environmental and Resource Economics},
   Volume = {31},
   Number = {2},
   Pages = {133-157},
   Publisher = {Springer Nature},
   Year = {2005},
   Month = {June},
   ISSN = {0924-6460},
   url = {http://www.nicholas.duke.edu/people/faculty/newell/ManagingPermitMarkets.pdf},
   Abstract = {The political economy of environmental policy favors the use
             of quantity-based instruments over price-based instruments
             (e.g., tradable permits over green taxes), at least in the
             United States. With cost uncertainty, however, there are
             clear efficiency advantages to prices in cases where the
             marginal damages of emissions are relatively flat, such as
             with greenhouse gases. The question arises, therefore, of
             whether one can design flexible quantity policies that mimic
             the behavior of price policies, namely stable permit prices
             and abatement costs. We explore a number of "quantity- plus"
             policies that replicate the behavior of a price policy
             through rules that adjust the effective permit cap for
             unexpectedly low or high costs. They do so without
             necessitating any monetary exchanges between the government
             and the regulated firms, which can be a significant
             political barrier to the use of price instruments. ©
             Springer 2005.},
   Doi = {10.1007/s10640-005-1761-y},
   Key = {fds267143}
}

@article{fds267131,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Sanchirico, JN and Kerr, S},
   Title = {Fishing quota markets},
   Journal = {Journal of Environmental Economics and Management},
   Volume = {49},
   Number = {3},
   Pages = {437-462},
   Publisher = {Elsevier BV},
   Year = {2005},
   Month = {January},
   ISSN = {0095-0696},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/10270 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {In 1986, New Zealand responded to the open-access problem by
             establishing the world's largest individual transferable
             quota (ITQ) system. Using a 15-year panel dataset from New
             Zealand that covers 33 species and more than 150 markets for
             fishing quotas, we assess trends in market activity, price
             dispersion, and the fundamentals determining quota prices.
             We find that market activity is sufficiently high in the
             economically important markets and that price dispersion has
             decreased. We also find evidence of economically rational
             behavior through the relationship between quota lease and
             sale prices and fishing output and input prices, ecological
             variability, and market interest rates. Controlling for
             these factors, our results show a greater increase in quota
             prices for fish stocks that faced significant reductions,
             consistent with increased profitability due to
             rationalization. Overall, this suggests that these markets
             are operating reasonably well, implying that ITQs can be
             effective instruments for efficient fisheries management. ©
             2004 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.},
   Doi = {10.1016/j.jeem.2004.06.005},
   Key = {fds267131}
}

@article{fds267142,
   Author = {Anderson, S and Newell, R},
   Title = {Prospects for carbon capture and storage
             technologies},
   Journal = {Annual Review of Environment and Resources},
   Volume = {29},
   Number = {1},
   Pages = {109-142},
   Publisher = {ANNUAL REVIEWS},
   Year = {2004},
   Month = {December},
   ISSN = {1543-5938},
   url = {http://www.nicholas.duke.edu/people/faculty/newell/annurev.energy.29.082703.pdf},
   Abstract = {Carbon capture and storage (CCS) technologies remove carbon
             dioxide from flue gases for storage in geologic formations
             or the ocean. We find that CCS is technically feasible, with
             current costs of about $200 to $250 per ton of carbon.
             Although currently a relatively expensive mitigation option,
             CCS could be attractive if we have a stringent carbon
             policy, if CCS turns out unexpectedly inexpensive relative
             to other options, or if it is otherwise desired to retain
             fossil fuels as part of the energy mix while reducing carbon
             emissions. Near-term prospects favor CCS for electric power
             plants and certain industrial sources with storage in
             depleted oil and gas reservoirs as opposed to aquifers. Deep
             aquifers may provide an attractive longer-term-storage
             option, whereas ocean storage poses greater technical and
             environmental uncertainty. CCS should be seriously
             considered for addressing climate change, alongside energy
             efficiency and carbon-free energy, although significant
             environmental, technical, and political uncertainties and
             obstacles remain.},
   Doi = {10.1146/annurev.energy.29.082703.145619},
   Key = {fds267142}
}

@article{fds267066,
   Author = {Palmer, K and Newell, R and Gillingham, K},
   Title = {Retrospective Examination of Demand-side Energy-efficiency
             Policies},
   Year = {2004},
   Month = {June},
   Abstract = {Energy efficiency policies are a primary avenue for reducing
             carbon emissions, with potential additional benefits from
             improved air quality and energy security. We review
             literature on a broad range of existing non-transportation
             energy efficiency policies covering appliance standards,
             financial incentives, information and voluntary programs,
             and government energy use (building and professional codes
             are not included). Estimates indicate these programs are
             likely to have collectively saved up to 4 quads of energy
             annually, with appliance standards and utility demand-side
             management likely making up at least half these savings.
             Energy Star, Climate Challenge, and 1605b voluntary
             emissions reductions may also contribute significantly to
             aggregate energy savings, but how much of these savings
             would have occurred absent these programs is less clear.
             Although even more uncertain, reductions in CO2, NOX, SO2,
             and PM-10 associated with energy savings may contribute
             about 10% more to the value of energy savings.},
   Key = {fds267066}
}

@article{fds267062,
   Author = {Kerr, S and Newell, RG and Sanchirico, JN},
   Title = {Evaluating the New Zealand individual transerable quota
             market for fisheries management},
   Pages = {121-134},
   Publisher = {OECD},
   Year = {2004},
   Month = {January},
   ISBN = {9789264015029},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264015036-6-en},
   Abstract = {Inshore fisheries depletion, the development of the
             quota-based programme for offshore fisheries, and the
             general orientation of the New Zealand government in the
             1980s toward deregulation, combined to create an atmosphere
             conducive to fundamental change in New Zealand fisheries
             management. After several years of consultation with
             industry, the Fisheries Amendment Act of 1986 was passed,
             creating New Zealand's individual transferable quota (ITQ)
             system. Modifying legislation has been passed several times
             since, but the basic structure of the system has remained
             intact. The system has been evaluated many times since its
             inception. Most evaluations have been qualitative in nature
             with the emphasis on identifying problems and improving the
             design of the regulations. The state of the fish stocks is
             reviewed regularly, though significant uncertainty remains.
             This report presents results from the first systematic
             assessment of the economic efficiency of the system. We
             assess only the likely cost efficiency of the ITQ market. We
             do not assess the environmental effects of the system and
             hence cannot comment on the overall economic efficiency of
             the regulation. We begin by giving a brief description of
             the ITQ system. We then discuss our motivation and the
             institutional framework for the evaluation. We discuss our
             methodology and basic results and then compare these with
             other evaluations of ITQ fisheries programmes and some other
             economic research on the New Zealand system.},
   Doi = {10.1787/9789264015036-6-en},
   Key = {fds267062}
}

@article{fds267122,
   Author = {Anderson, ST and Newell, RG},
   Title = {Information programs for technology adoption: The case of
             energy-efficiency audits},
   Journal = {Resource and Energy Economics},
   Volume = {26},
   Number = {1},
   Pages = {27-50},
   Publisher = {Elsevier BV},
   Year = {2004},
   Month = {January},
   ISSN = {0928-7655},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/6424 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {We analyze technology adoption decisions of manufacturing
             plants in response to government-sponsored energy audits.
             Overall, plants adopt about half of the recommended
             energy-efficiency projects. Using fixed effects logit
             estimation, we find that adoption rates are higher for
             projects with shorter paybacks, lower costs, greater annual
             savings, higher energy prices, and greater energy
             conservation. Plants are 40% more responsive to initial
             costs than annual savings, suggesting that subsidies may be
             more effective at promoting energy-efficient technologies
             than energy price increases. Adoption decisions imply hurdle
             rates of 50-100%, which is consistent with the investment
             criteria small and medium-size firms state they use. © 2003
             Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.},
   Doi = {10.1016/j.reseneeco.2003.07.001},
   Key = {fds267122}
}

@article{fds267134,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Pizer, WA},
   Title = {Uncertain discount rates in climate policy
             analysis},
   Journal = {Energy Policy},
   Volume = {32},
   Number = {4},
   Pages = {519-529},
   Publisher = {Elsevier BV},
   Year = {2004},
   Month = {January},
   ISSN = {0301-4215},
   url = {http://www.nicholas.duke.edu/people/faculty/newell/EnergyPolicy.pdf},
   Abstract = {Consequences in the distant future-such as those from
             climate change-have little value today when discounted using
             conventional rates. This result contradicts our "gut
             feeling" about such problems and often leads to ad hoc
             application of lower rates for valuations over longer
             horizons-a step facilitated by confusion and disagreement
             over the correct rate even over short horizons. We review
             the theory and intuition behind the choice of discount rates
             now and, importantly, the impact of likely variation in
             rates in the future. Correlated changes in future rates
             imply that the distant future should be discounted at much
             lower rates than suggested by the current rate, thereby
             raising the value of future consequences-regardless of
             opinions concerning the current rate. Using historic data to
             quantity the likely changes and correlation in changes in
             future rates, we find that future valuations rise by a
             factor of many thousands at horizons of 300 years or more,
             almost doubling the expected present value of climate
             mitigation benefits relative to constant 4% discounting.
             Ironically, uncertainty about future rates reduces the ratio
             of valuations based on alternate choices of the current
             rate. © 2003 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.},
   Doi = {10.1016/S0301-4215(03)00153-8},
   Key = {fds267134}
}

@article{fds365725,
   Author = {Jaffe, AB and Newell, RG and Stavins, RN},
   Title = {Technology Policy for Energy and the Environment},
   Journal = {Innovation Policy and the Economy},
   Volume = {4},
   Pages = {35-68},
   Publisher = {University of Chicago Press},
   Year = {2004},
   Month = {January},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/ipe.4.25056161},
   Doi = {10.1086/ipe.4.25056161},
   Key = {fds365725}
}

@article{fds267138,
   Author = {Anderson, S and Newell, RG},
   Title = {Simplified marginal effects in discrete choice
             models},
   Journal = {Economics Letters},
   Volume = {81},
   Number = {3},
   Pages = {321-326},
   Publisher = {Elsevier BV},
   Year = {2003},
   Month = {December},
   ISSN = {0165-1765},
   url = {http://www.nicholas.duke.edu/people/faculty/newell/EconLetters.pdf},
   Abstract = {We show that with a simple normalization of explanatory
             variables, marginal effects in probit and logit models
             simplify dramatically, becoming a function of only the
             estimated constant term. Related simplifications hold for
             computation of asymptotic variances of these effects. ©
             2003 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.},
   Doi = {10.1016/S0165-1765(03)00212-X},
   Key = {fds267138}
}

@article{fds267115,
   Author = {Boyd, J and Burtraw, D and Krupnick, A and McConnell, V and Newell, RG and Palmer, K and Sanchirico, JN and Walls, M},
   Title = {Trading cases},
   Journal = {Environmental Science & Technology},
   Volume = {37},
   Number = {11},
   Pages = {216A-223A},
   Year = {2003},
   Month = {June},
   ISSN = {0013-936X},
   url = {http://www.nicholas.duke.edu/faculty/Newell/EST.pdf},
   Abstract = {Trading credits and market-based solutions are steadily
             replacing command-and-control policies, But how effective
             are these programs, and do they really achieve their goals?
             James Boyd, Dallas Burtraw, Alan Krupnick, Virginia
             McConnell, Richard Newell, Karen Palmer, James Sanchirico,
             and Margaret Walls - all with Resources for the Future -
             look at the successes and failures of five very different
             trading programs.},
   Doi = {10.1021/es032462t},
   Key = {fds267115}
}

@article{fds267114,
   Author = {Jaffe, AB and Newell, RG and Stavins, RN},
   Title = {Chapter 11 Technological change and the environment},
   Journal = {Handbook of Environmental Economics},
   Volume = {1},
   Pages = {461-516},
   Publisher = {Elsevier},
   Year = {2003},
   Month = {January},
   ISSN = {1574-0099},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S1574-0099(03)01016-7},
   Abstract = {Environmental policy discussions increasingly focus on
             issues related to technological change. This is partly
             because the environmental consequences of social activity
             are frequently affected by the rate and direction of
             technological change, and partly because environmental
             policy interventions can themselves create constraints and
             incentives that have significant effects on the path of
             technological progress. This chapter summarizes current
             thinking on technological change in the broader economics
             literature, surveys the growing economic literature on the
             interaction between technology and the environment, and
             explores the normative implications of these analyses. We
             begin with a brief overview of the economics of
             technological change, and then examine theory and empirical
             evidence on invention, innovation, and diffusion and the
             related literature on the effects of environmental policy on
             the creation of new, environmentally friendly technology. We
             conclude with suggestions for further research on
             technological change and the environment. © 2003 Elsevier
             Science B.V. All rights reserved.},
   Doi = {10.1016/S1574-0099(03)01016-7},
   Key = {fds267114}
}

@article{fds267129,
   Author = {Kerr, S and Newell, RG},
   Title = {Policy-induced technology adoption: Evidence from the U.S.
             lead phasedown},
   Journal = {Journal of Industrial Economics},
   Volume = {51},
   Number = {3},
   Pages = {317-343},
   Publisher = {WILEY},
   Year = {2003},
   Month = {Fall},
   ISSN = {0022-1821},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/9131 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {Theory suggests that economic instruments, such as pollution
             taxes or tradable permits, can provide more efficient
             technology adoption incentives than conventional regulatory
             standards. We explore this issue for an important industry
             undergoing dramatic decreases in allowed pollution - the
             U.S. petroleum industry's phasedown of lead in gasoline.
             Using a duration model applied to a panel of refineries from
             1971-1995, we find that the pattern of technology adoption
             is consistent with an economic response to market
             incentives, plant characteristics, and alternative policies.
             Importantly, evidence suggests that the tradable permit
             system used during the phasedown provided incentives for
             more efficient technology adoption decisions.},
   Doi = {10.1111/1467-6451.00203},
   Key = {fds267129}
}

@article{fds267139,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Stavins, RN},
   Title = {Cost Heterogeneity and the Potential Savings from
             Market-Based Policies},
   Journal = {Journal of Regulatory Economics},
   Volume = {23},
   Number = {1},
   Pages = {43-59},
   Year = {2003},
   Month = {January},
   ISSN = {0922-680X},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/6757 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {Policy makers and analysts are often faced with situations
             where it is unclear whether market-based instruments hold
             real promise of reducing costs, relative to conventional
             uniform standards. We develop analytic expressions that can
             be employed with modest amounts of information to estimate
             the potential cost savings associated with market-based
             policies, with an application to the environmental policy
             realm. These simple formulae can identify instruments that
             merit more detailed investigation. We illustrate the use of
             these results with an application to nitrogen oxides control
             by electric utilities in the United States.},
   Doi = {10.1023/A:1021879330491},
   Key = {fds267139}
}

@article{fds267140,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Pizer, WA},
   Title = {Discounting the distant future: How much do uncertain rates
             increase valuations?},
   Journal = {Journal of Environmental Economics and Management},
   Volume = {46},
   Number = {1},
   Pages = {52-71},
   Publisher = {Elsevier BV},
   Year = {2003},
   Month = {January},
   ISSN = {0095-0696},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/9133 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {We demonstrate that when the future path of the discount
             rate is uncertain and highly correlated, the distant future
             should be discounted at significantly lower rates than
             suggested by the current rate. We then use two centuries of
             US interest rate data to quantify this effect. Using both
             random walk and mean-reverting models, we compute the
             "certainty-equivalent rate" that summarizes the effect of
             uncertainty and measures the appropriate forward rate of
             discount in the future. Under the random walk model we find
             that the certainty-equivalent rate falls continuously from
             4% to 2% after 100 years, 1% after 200 years, and 0.5% after
             300 years. At horizons of 400 years, the discounted value
             increases by a factor of over 40,000 relative to
             conventional discounting. Applied to climate change
             mitigation, we find that incorporating discount rate
             uncertainty almost doubles the expected present value of
             mitigation benefits. © 2003 Elsevier Science (USA). All
             rights reserved.},
   Doi = {10.1016/S0095-0696(02)00031-1},
   Key = {fds267140}
}

@article{fds267141,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Pizer, WA},
   Title = {Regulating stock externalities under uncertainty},
   Journal = {Journal of Environmental Economics and Management},
   Volume = {45},
   Number = {2 SUPPL.},
   Pages = {416-432},
   Publisher = {Elsevier BV},
   Year = {2003},
   Month = {January},
   ISSN = {0095-0696},
   url = {http://www.nicholas.duke.edu/people/faculty/newell/JEEMstocks.pdf},
   Abstract = {Using a simple analytical model incorporating benefits of a
             stock, costs of adjusting the stock, and uncertainty in
             costs, we uncover several important principles governing the
             choice of price-based policies (e.g., taxes) relative to
             quantity-based policies (e.g., tradable permits) for
             controlling stock externalities. As in Weitzman (Rev.
             Econom. Stud. 41(4) (1974) 477), the relative slopes of the
             marginal benefits and costs of controlling the externality
             continue to be critical determinants of the efficiency of
             prices relative to quantities, with flatter marginal
             benefits and steeper marginal costs favoring prices. But
             some important adjustments for dynamic effects are
             necessary, including correlation of cost shocks across time,
             discounting, stock decay, and the rate of benefits growth.
             Applied to the problem of greenhouse gases and climate
             change, we find that a price-based instrument generates
             several times the expected net benefits of a quantity
             instrument. © 2003 Elsevier Science (USA). All rights
             reserved.},
   Doi = {10.1016/S0095-0696(02)00016-5},
   Key = {fds267141}
}

@article{fds289606,
   Author = {Stavins, RN and Newell, RG},
   Title = {Cost Heterogeneity and the Potential Savings from
             Market-Based Policies},
   Year = {2002},
   Month = {July},
   Abstract = {Policy makers and analysts are often faced with situations
             where it is unclear whether market-based instruments hold
             real promise of reducing costs, relative to conventional
             uniform standards. We develop analytic expressions that can
             be employed with modest amounts of information to estimate
             the potential cost savings associated with market-based
             policies, with an application to the environmental policy
             realm. These simple formulae can help increase intuition and
             understanding of the sources of cost savings, and help
             identify and design instruments that merit more detailed
             investigation. We illustrate the use of these results with
             an application to nitrogen oxides control by electric
             utilities in the United States.},
   Key = {fds289606}
}

@article{fds267110,
   Author = {Newell, R and Pizer, W},
   Title = {Discounting the Benefits of Climate Change Policies Using
             Uncertain Rates},
   Journal = {Resources},
   Volume = {Winter},
   Number = {146},
   Pages = {15-20},
   Publisher = {Washington, D.C. Resources for the Future,
             Inc.},
   Year = {2002},
   Month = {January},
   ISSN = {0048-7376},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/7075 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {Evaluating environmental policies, such as the mitigation of
             greenhouse gases, frequently requires balancing near-term
             mitigation costs against long-term environmental benefits.
             Conventional approaches to valuing such investments hold
             interest rates constant, but the authors contend that there
             is a real degree of uncertainty in future interest rates.
             This leads to a higher valuation of future benefits relative
             to conventional methods that ignore interest rate
             uncertainty.},
   Key = {fds267110}
}

@article{fds267137,
   Author = {Jaffe, AB and Newell, RG and Stavins, RN},
   Title = {Environmental policy and technological change},
   Journal = {Environmental and Resource Economics},
   Volume = {22},
   Number = {1-2},
   Pages = {41-70},
   Year = {2002},
   Month = {January},
   ISSN = {0924-6460},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/10271 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {The relationship between technological change and
             environmental policy has received increasing attention from
             scholars and policy makers alike over the past ten years.
             This is partly because the environmental impacts of social
             activity are significantly affected by technological change,
             and partly because environmental policy interventions
             themselves create new constraints and incentives that affect
             the process of technological developments. Our central
             purpose in this article is to provide environmental
             economists with a useful guide to research on technological
             change and the analytical tools that can be used to explore
             further the interaction between technology and the
             environment. In Part 1 of the article, we provide an
             overview of analytical frameworks for investigating the
             economics of technological change, highlighting key issues
             for the researcher. In Part 2, we turn our attention to
             theoretical analysis of the effects of environmental policy
             on technological change, and in Part 3, we focus on issues
             related to the empirical analysis of technology innovation
             and diffusion. Finally, we conclude in Part 4 with some
             additional suggestions for research.},
   Doi = {10.1023/A:1015519401088},
   Key = {fds267137}
}

@article{fds267048,
   Author = {Jaffe, AB and Newell, RG and Stavins, RN},
   Title = {Technological Change and the Environment},
   Year = {2001},
   Month = {October},
   Abstract = {Environmental policy discussions increasingly focus on
             issues related to technological change. This is partly
             because the environmental consequences of social activity
             are frequently affected by the rate and direction of
             technological change, and partly because environmental
             policy interventions can themselves create constraints and
             incentives that have significant effects on the path of
             technological progress. This paper, prepared as a chapter
             draft for the forthcoming Handbook of Environmental
             Economics (North-Holland/Elsevier Science), summarizes
             current thinking on technological change in the broader
             economics literature, surveys the growing economic
             literature on the interaction between technology and the
             environment, and explores the normative implications of
             these analyses. We begin with a brief overview of the
             economics of technological change, and then examine theory
             and empirical evidence on invention, innovation, and
             diffusion and the related literature on the effects of
             environmental policy on the creation of new, environmentally
             friendly technology. We conclude with suggestions for
             further research on technological change and the
             environment.},
   Key = {fds267048}
}

@article{fds267052,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Pizer, WA},
   Title = {Discounting the Distant Future: How Much Do Uncertain Rates
             Increase Valuations?},
   Year = {2001},
   Month = {May},
   Abstract = {Costs and benefits in the distant future, such as those
             associated with global warming, long-lived infrastructure,
             hazardous and radioactive waste, and biodiversity often have
             little value today when measured with conventional discount
             rates. We demonstrate that when the future path of this
             conventional rate is uncertain and persistent (i.e., highly
             correlated over time), the distant future should be
             discounted at lower rates than suggested by the current
             rate. We then use two centuries of data on U.S. interest
             rates to quantify this effect. Using both random walk and
             mean-reverting models, we compute the certainty-equivalent
             rate that is, the single discount rate that summarizes the
             effect of uncertainty and measures the appropriate forward
             rate of discount in the future. Using the random walk model,
             which we consider more compelling, we find that the
             certainty-equivalent rate falls from 4%, to 2% after 100
             years, 1% after 200 years, and 0.5% after 300 years. If we
             use these rates to value consequences at horizons of 400
             years, the discounted value increases by a factor of over
             40,000 relative to conventional discounting. Applying the
             random walk model to the consequences of climate change, we
             find that inclusion of discount rate uncertainty almost
             doubles the expected present value of mitigation
             benefits.},
   Key = {fds267052}
}

@article{fds267049,
   Author = {Jaffe, AB and Newell, RG and Stavins, RN},
   Title = {Technological Change and the Environment},
   Year = {2000},
   Month = {October},
   Abstract = {Environmental policy discussions increasingly focus on
             issues related to technological change. This is partly
             because the environmental consequences of social activity
             are frequently affected by the rate and direction of
             technological change, and partly because environmental
             policy interventions can themselves create constraints and
             incentives that have significant effects on the path of
             technological progress. This paper, prepared as a chapter
             draft for the forthcoming Handbook of Environmental
             Economics (North-Holland/Elsevier Science), summarizes for
             environmental economists current thinking on technological
             change in the broader economics literature, surveys the
             growing economic literature on the interaction between
             technology and the environment, and explores the normative
             implications of these analyses. We begin with a brief
             overview of the economics of technological change, and then
             examine three important areas where technology and the
             environment intersect: the theory and empirical evidence of
             induced innovation and the related literature on the effects
             of environmental policy on the creation of new,
             environmentally friendly technology; the theory and empirics
             of environmental issues related to technology diffusion; and
             analyses of the comparative technological impacts of
             alternative environmental policy instruments. We conclude
             with suggestions for further research on technological
             change and the environment.},
   Key = {fds267049}
}

@article{fds267136,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Stavins, RN},
   Title = {Climate change and forest sinks: Factors affecting the costs
             of carbon sequestration},
   Journal = {Journal of Environmental Economics and Management},
   Volume = {40},
   Number = {3},
   Pages = {211-235},
   Publisher = {Elsevier BV},
   Year = {2000},
   Month = {January},
   ISSN = {0095-0696},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/10272 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {The possibility of encouraging the growth of forests as a
             means of sequestering carbon dioxide has received
             considerable attention, partly because of evidence that this
             can be a relatively inexpensive means of combating climate
             change. But how sensitive are such estimates to specific
             conditions? We examine the sensitivity of carbon
             sequestration costs to changes in critical factors,
             including the nature of management and deforestation
             regimes, silvicultural species, relative prices, and
             discount rates. (C) 2000 Academic Press.},
   Doi = {10.1006/jeem.1999.1120},
   Key = {fds267136}
}

@article{fds267054,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Stavins, RN},
   Title = {Abatement-Cost Heterogeneity and Anticipated Savings from
             Market-Based Environmental Policies},
   Year = {1999},
   Month = {December},
   Abstract = {Policy makers and policy analysts in the environmental realm
             are frequently faced with situations where it is unclear
             whether market-based instruments hold real promise of
             reducing costs, relative to conventional command-and-control
             approaches. We develop some simple rules-of-thumb that can
             be employed with minimal amounts of information to estimate
             the potential cost savings that can be anticipated from
             designing and implementing market-based policy instruments.
             Because our analytical models are simple, yet capture key
             properties of pollution abatement cost functions, they can
             be used to predict potential cost savings through simple
             formulae. Our hope is that these simple formulae can aid
             policy analysts and policy makers in the early stages of
             exploring alternative policy instruments by helping them
             identify approaches that merit greater attention and more
             detailed analysis.},
   Key = {fds267054}
}

@article{fds267057,
   Author = {Jaffe, AB and Newell, RG and Stavins, RN},
   Title = {Energy-Efficient Technologies and Climate Change Policies:
             Issues and Evidence},
   Pages = {171-181},
   Booktitle = {Climate Change Economics and Policy: An RFF Anthology
             (Chapter 17)},
   Publisher = {RFF Press, Washington, DC},
   Editor = {M. Toman},
   Year = {1999},
   Month = {December},
   url = {http://www.nicholas.duke.edu/people/faculty/newell/chap2017.pdf},
   Abstract = {Enhanced energy efficiency occupies a central role in
             evaluating the efficacy and cost of climate change policies.
             Ultimately, total greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions are the
             product of population, economic activity per capita, energy
             use per unit of economic activity, and the carbon intensity
             of energy used. Although greenhouse gas emissions can be
             limited by reducing economic activity, this option obviously
             has little appeal even to rich countries, let alone poor
             ones. Much attention has therefore been placed on the role
             that technological improvements can play in reducing carbon
             emissions and in lowering the cost of those reductions. In
             addition, the influence of technological changes on the
             emission, concentration, and cost of reducing GHGs will tend
             to overwhelm other factors, especially in the longer term.
             Understanding the process of technological change is
             therefore of utmost importance. Nonetheless, the task of
             measuring, modeling, and ultimately influencing the path of
             technological development is fraught with complexity and
             uncertainty?as are the technologies themselves. Although
             there is little debate over the importance of energy
             efficiency in limiting GHG emissions, there is intense
             debate about its cost-effectiveness and about the government
             policies that should be pursued to enhance energy
             efficiency. At the risk of excessive simplification, we can
             characterize "technologists" as believing that there are
             plentiful opportunities for low-cost, or even
             "negative-cost" improvements in energy efficiency, and that
             realizing these opportunities will require active
             intervention in markets for energy-using equipment to help
             overcome barriers to the use of more efficient technologies.
             Most economists, on the other hand, acknowledge that there
             are "market barriers" to the penetration of various
             technologies that enhance energy efficiency, but that only
             some of these barriers represent real "market failures" that
             reduce economic efficiency. In this essay, we examine what
             lies behind this dichotomy in perspectives. Ultimately, the
             veracity of different perspectives is an empirical question
             and reliable empirical evidence on the issues identified
             above is surprisingly limited. We review the evidence that
             is available, finding that although energy and technology
             markets certainly are not perfect (no markets are), the
             balance of evidence supports the view that there is not as
             much "free lunch" in energy efficiency as some would
             suggest. On the other hand, a case can be made for the
             existence of certain inefficiencies in energy technology
             markets, thus raising the possibility of some inexpensive
             GHG control through energy-efficiency enhancement. We
             conclude with some reflections on the role of appropriate
             energy efficiency policy in climate change
             mitigation.},
   Key = {fds267057}
}

@article{fds267135,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Jaffe, AB and Stavins, RN},
   Title = {The induced innovation hypothesis and energy-saving
             technological change},
   Journal = {The Quarterly Journal of Economics},
   Volume = {114},
   Number = {3},
   Pages = {941-975},
   Publisher = {Oxford University Press (OUP)},
   Year = {1999},
   Month = {January},
   ISSN = {0033-5533},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/9135 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {We develop a methodology for testing Hicks's induced
             innovation hypothesis by estimating a product-characteristics
             model of energy-using consumer durables, augmenting the
             hypothesis to allow for the influence of government
             regulations. For the products we explored, the evidence
             suggests that (i) the rate of overall innovation was
             independent of energy prices and regulations; (ii) the
             direction of innovation was responsive to energy price
             changes for some products but not for others; (iii) energy
             price changes induced changes in the subset of technically
             feasible models that were offered for sale; (iv) this
             responsiveness increased substantially during the period
             after energy-efficiency product labeling was required; and
             (v) nonetheless, a sizable portion of efficiency
             improvements were autonomous.},
   Doi = {10.1162/003355399556188},
   Key = {fds267135}
}

@article{fds361819,
   Author = {Berg, M and Nevin, R and Newell, R},
   Title = {Overview: Waste management},
   Journal = {Environment: Science and Policy for Sustainable
             Development},
   Volume = {34},
   Number = {10},
   Pages = {2-3},
   Year = {1992},
   Month = {January},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00139157.1992.9930936},
   Doi = {10.1080/00139157.1992.9930936},
   Key = {fds361819}
}

@article{fds267093,
   Author = {NEWELL, RG and FEUSTON, BP and GAROFALINI, SH},
   Title = {THE STRUCTURE OF SODIUM TRISILICATE GLASS VIA
             MOLECULAR-DYNAMICS EMPLOYING 3-BODY POTENTIALS},
   Journal = {Journal of Materials Research},
   Volume = {4},
   Number = {2},
   Pages = {434-439},
   Publisher = {Cambridge University Press (CUP)},
   Year = {1989},
   ISSN = {0884-2914},
   url = {http://gateway.webofknowledge.com/gateway/Gateway.cgi?GWVersion=2&SrcApp=PARTNER_APP&SrcAuth=LinksAMR&KeyUT=WOS:A1989T619400029&DestLinkType=FullRecord&DestApp=ALL_WOS&UsrCustomerID=47d3190e77e5a3a53558812f597b0b92},
   Doi = {10.1557/JMR.1989.0434},
   Key = {fds267093}
}

@article{fds267092,
   Author = {Feuston, BP and Newell, RN and Garofalini, SH},
   Title = {Application of a New Three-Body Potential to Vitreous Silica
             and Sodium Silicate Glasses},
   Journal = {Materials Research Society Symposium Proceedings},
   Volume = {141},
   Publisher = {Springer Science and Business Media LLC},
   Year = {1988},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1557/proc-141-207},
   Abstract = {<jats:title>Abstract</jats:title><jats:p>An empirical
             three-body potential, suitable for molecular dynamics (MD)
             simulations, has been developed to model the natural
             covalency of the Si-O bond in vitreous silica and silicate
             glass systems. Through the addition of a small
             directional-dependent three-body term to a previously used
             modified ionic pair interaction, a narrow distribution of
             tetrahedral angles and a low concentration of defects were
             obtained, in good agreement with experiment. The structure
             of bulk silica resulting from the MD technique also
             contained a larger average ring size, no edge-sharing
             tetrahedra, and a calculated static structure factor in good
             agreement with neutron diffraction results. The simulated
             sodium silicate glass was also largely improved over
             previous simulations using pair interactions alone. All
             silicon atoms were found to be exactly four coordinated
             while the number of non-bridging oxygen nearly equaled the
             number of sodium ions present with a reasonable distribution
             of Q<jats:sub>i</jats:sub> species.</jats:p>},
   Doi = {10.1557/proc-141-207},
   Key = {fds267092}
}


%% Other   
@misc{fds351202,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Stavins, RN},
   Title = {Climate change and forest sinks: Factors affecting the costs
             of carbon sequestration},
   Pages = {321-345},
   Booktitle = {Climate Change},
   Year = {2017},
   Month = {November},
   ISBN = {9780815388081},
   Abstract = {The possibility of encouraging the growth of forests as a
             means of sequestering carbon dioxide has received
             considerable attention, partly because of evidence that this
             can be a relatively inexpensive means of combating climate
             change. But how sensitive are such estimates to specific
             conditions? We examine the sensitivity of carbon
             sequestration costs to changes in critical factors,
             including the nature of management and deforestation
             regimes, silvicultural species, relative prices, and
             discount rates.},
   Key = {fds351202}
}

@misc{fds333909,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Raimi, D},
   Title = {Oil and Gas Revenue Allocation to Local Governments in Eight
             States},
   Year = {2015},
   Month = {October},
   Key = {fds333909}
}

@misc{fds267042,
   Author = {Newell, RG},
   Title = {The role of energy technology policy alongside carbon
             pricing},
   Pages = {178-190},
   Booktitle = {Implementing a US Carbon Tax: Challenges and
             Debates},
   Year = {2015},
   Month = {February},
   ISBN = {9781138814158},
   Key = {fds267042}
}

@misc{fds267091,
   Author = {Raimi, D and Newell, RG},
   Title = {Shale Public Finance: Local government revenues and costs
             associated with oil and gas development},
   Booktitle = {Shale Public Finance: Local government revenues and costs
             associated with oil and gas development},
   Year = {2014},
   Month = {May},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/9216 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {Oil and gas development associated with shale resources has
             increased substantially in the United States, with important
             implications for local governments. These governments tend
             to experience increased revenue from a variety of sources,
             such as severance taxes distributed by the state government,
             local property taxes and sales taxes, direct payments from
             oil and gas companies, and in-kind contributions from those
             companies. Local governments also tend to face increased
             demand for services such as road repairs due to heavy truck
             traffic and from population growth associated with the oil
             and gas sector. This paper describes the major oil- and gas
             related revenues and service demands (i.e., costs) that
             county and municipal governments have experienced in
             Arkansas, Colorado, Louisiana, Montana, North Dakota,
             Pennsylvania, Texas, and Wyoming. Based on extensive
             interviews with officials in the most heavily affected parts
             of these states, along with analysis of financial data, it
             appears that most county and municipal governments have
             experienced net financial benefits, though some in western
             North Dakota and eastern Montana appear to have experienced
             net negative fiscal impacts. Some municipalities in rural
             Colorado and Wyoming also struggled to manage fiscal impacts
             during recent oil and gas booms, though these challenges
             faded as drilling activity slowed.},
   Key = {fds267091}
}

@misc{fds267073,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Iler, S},
   Title = {The Global Energy Outlook},
   Booktitle = {Energy & Security: Towards a New Foreign Policy
             Strategy},
   Publisher = {Johns Hopkins University Press},
   Editor = {Kalicky, J and Goldwyn, D},
   Year = {2013},
   Abstract = {We explore the principal trends that are shaping the future
             landscape of energy supply, demand, and trade.},
   Key = {fds267073}
}

@misc{fds267088,
   Author = {Newell, RG},
   Title = {Inducing innovation for climate change mitigation},
   Pages = {20-21},
   Booktitle = {Issues of the Day: 100 Commentaries on Climate, Energy, the
             Environment, Transportation, and Public Health
             Policy},
   Year = {2012},
   Month = {January},
   ISBN = {9781936331253},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.4324/9781936331253},
   Doi = {10.4324/9781936331253},
   Key = {fds267088}
}

@misc{fds267106,
   Author = {Henderson, Rebecca M. and Newell, R},
   Title = {Introduction and Summary},
   Pages = {1-23},
   Booktitle = {Accelerating Energy Innovation: Insights from Multiple
             Sectors},
   Publisher = {University of Chicago Press for the National Bureau of
             Economic Research},
   Editor = {Henderson, RM and Newell, RG},
   Year = {2011},
   Month = {May},
   ISBN = {0226326837},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/7427 Duke open
             access},
   Key = {fds267106}
}

@misc{fds267108,
   Author = {Newell, R},
   Title = {The Energy Innovation System: A Historical
             Perspective},
   Pages = {25-47},
   Booktitle = {Accelerating energy innovation: insights from multiple
             sectors},
   Publisher = {University of Chicago Press},
   Editor = {Henderson, RM and Newell, RG},
   Year = {2011},
   Month = {January},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/7373 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {Accelerating energy innovation could be an important part of
             an effective response to the threat of climate change.
             Written by a stellar group of experts in the field, this
             book complements existing research on the subject with an
             exploration of the role that public and private policy have
             played in enabling--and sustaining--swift innovation in a
             variety of industries, from agriculture and the life
             sciences to information technology. Chapters highlight the
             factors that have determined the impact of past policies,
             and suggest that effectively managed federal funding,
             strategies to increase customer demand, and the enabling of
             aggressive competition from new firms are important
             ingredients for policies that affect innovative
             activity.},
   Key = {fds267108}
}

@misc{fds315887,
   Author = {Fischer, C and Newell, RG},
   Title = {Comparing environmental and technology policies for climate
             mitigation and renewable energy},
   Pages = {77-108},
   Booktitle = {Current Affairs: Perspectives on Electricity Policy for
             Ontario},
   Year = {2010},
   Month = {January},
   ISBN = {9781442609945},
   Key = {fds315887}
}

@misc{fds365723,
   Title = {Literature Review of Recent Trends and Future Prospects for
             Innovation in Climate Change Mitigation},
   Publisher = {Organisation for Economic Co-Operation and Development
             (OECD)},
   Year = {2009},
   Month = {December},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/218688342302},
   Doi = {10.1787/218688342302},
   Key = {fds365723}
}

@misc{fds267105,
   Author = {Newell, RG},
   Title = {International climate technology strategies},
   Pages = {403-438},
   Booktitle = {Post-Kyoto International Climate Policy: Implementing
             Architectures for Agreement: Research from the Harvard
             Project on International Climate Agreements},
   Publisher = {Cambridge University Press},
   Year = {2009},
   Month = {January},
   ISBN = {9780521137850},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/7455 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {Introduction There is widespread agreement that achieving
             the very substantial reductions in greenhouse gas (GHG)
             emissions necessary to stabilize atmospheric carbon dioxide
             (CO2) concentrations at 450–550 parts per million (ppm)
             will require innovation and large-scale adoption of
             GHG-reducing technologies throughout the global energy
             system (IPCC 2007). The set of necessary technologies
             includes those for increased energy efficiency, renewable
             energy, nuclear power, and CO2 capture and storage.
             Alongside strategies aimed at reducing GHG emissions—such
             as emission targets in an international context or domestic
             GHG cap-and-trade systems or taxes—much discussion has
             therefore focused on policies that also target technology
             directly, including research and development (R&D)
             activities and technology-specific mandates and incentives.
             The associated policy debate is not so much over the
             importance of new technology per se in solving the climate
             problem, but rather over what the most effective policies
             and institutions are for achieving the dramatic
             technological changes necessary to stabilize GHG
             concentrations. The scale of the system to be reoriented is
             immense. The International Energy Agency (IEA), in its most
             recent assessment of energy investment, projects that about
             $22 trillion of investment in energy-supply infrastructure
             will be needed over the 2006–2030 period, or almost $900
             billion annually, on average (IEA 2007b). Note that this
             does not include expenditures on energy demand-side
             technologies (e.g., transportation, appliances, and
             equipment), which will measure in the trillions of dollars
             each year.},
   Doi = {10.1017/CBO9780511813207.014},
   Key = {fds267105}
}

@misc{fds267099,
   Author = {Newell, R},
   Title = {A U.S. Innovation Strategy for Climate Change
             Mitigation},
   Series = {Hamilton Project Discussion Paper 2008-15},
   Pages = {49 pages},
   Publisher = {Brookings Institution},
   Year = {2008},
   Month = {December},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/7546 Duke open
             access},
   Key = {fds267099}
}

@misc{fds267102,
   Author = {Newell, R},
   Title = {U.S. Climate Mitigation in the Context of Global
             Stabilization},
   Pages = {38-51},
   Booktitle = {Assessing U.S. Climate Policy Options: A Report Summarizing
             Work at RFF as Part of the Inter-Industry U.S. Climate
             Policy Forum},
   Publisher = {Resources for the Future},
   Editor = {Resources for the Future},
   Year = {2008},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/7543 Duke open
             access},
   Key = {fds267102}
}

@misc{fds267104,
   Author = {Rai, A and Newell, R and Reichman, J and Wiener, J},
   Title = {Intellectual Property and Alternatives: Strategies for Green
             Innovation},
   Series = {Energy, Environment and Development Programme Paper
             08/03},
   Pages = {39 pages},
   Publisher = {Chatham House, UK},
   Year = {2008},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/7540 Duke open
             access},
   Key = {fds267104}
}

@misc{fds267100,
   Author = {Newell, R},
   Title = {Climate Technology Deployment Policy},
   Pages = {133-145},
   Booktitle = {Assessing U.S. Climate Policy Options: A Report Summarizing
             Work at RFF as Part of the Inter-Industry U.S. Climate
             Policy Forum},
   Publisher = {Resources for the Future},
   Year = {2007},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/7545 Duke open
             access},
   Key = {fds267100}
}

@misc{fds267101,
   Author = {Newell, R},
   Title = {Climate Technology Research, Development, and Demonstration:
             Funding Sources, Institutions, and Instruments},
   Pages = {117-132},
   Booktitle = {Assessing U.S. Climate Policy Options: A Report Summarizing
             Work at RFF as Part of the Inter-Industry U.S. Climate
             Policy Forum},
   Publisher = {Resources for the Future},
   Year = {2007},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/7544 Duke open
             access},
   Key = {fds267101}
}

@misc{fds267109,
   Author = {Newell, R and Rogers, K},
   Title = {The Market-Based Lead Phasedown},
   Pages = {173-193},
   Booktitle = {Moving to Markets in Environmental Regulation : Lessons from
             Twenty Years of Experience},
   Publisher = {Oxford University Press, USA},
   Editor = {Freeman, J and Kolstad, CD},
   Year = {2006},
   Month = {November},
   ISBN = {0198040865},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/7372 Duke open
             access},
   Abstract = {Over the last decade, market-based incentives have become
             the regulatorytool of choice when trying to solve difficult
             environmental problems. Evidenceof their dominance can be
             seen in recent proposals for addressing global
             warming(through an emissions trading scheme in the Kyoto
             Protocol) and for amending theClean Air Act (to add a new
             emissions trading systems for smog precursors
             andmercury--the Bush administration's "Clear Skies"
             program). They are widelyviewed as more efficient than
             traditional command and control regulation. Thiscollection
             of essays takes a critical look at this question, and
             evaluateswhether the promises of market-based regulation
             have been fulfilled.Contributors put forth the ideas that
             few regulatory instruments are actuallypurely market-based,
             or purely prescriptive, and that both approaches can
             besystematically undermined by insufficiently careful design
             and by failures ofmonitoring and enforcement. All in all,
             the essays recommend future researchthat no longer pits one
             kind of approach against the other, but instead
             examinestheir interaction and compatibility. This book
             should appeal to academics inenvironmental economics and
             law, along with policymakers in government agenciesand
             advocates in non-governmental organizations.},
   Doi = {10.1093/acprof:oso/9780195189650.003.0007},
   Key = {fds267109}
}

@misc{fds152182,
   Author = {R.G. Newell},
   Title = {What's the big deal about oil? How we can get oil policy
             right},
   Journal = {Resources},
   Volume = {163},
   Pages = {6-10},
   Year = {2006},
   Month = {Fall},
   Key = {fds152182}
}

@misc{fds152184,
   Author = {Newell, R.G.},
   Title = {The hydrogen economy: Laying out the groundwork},
   Journal = {Resources},
   Volume = {156},
   Pages = {20-23},
   Year = {2005},
   url = {http://www.nicholas.duke.edu/people/faculty/newell/NewellResourcesHydrogen.pdf},
   Key = {fds152184}
}

@misc{fds267061,
   Author = {Newell, RG and Rogers, K},
   Title = {Leaded gasoline in the United States: The breakthrough of
             permit trading},
   Volume = {9781936331468},
   Pages = {175-191},
   Booktitle = {Choosing Environmental Policy: Comparing Instruments and
             Outcomes In the United States and Europe},
   Publisher = {Routledge},
   Year = {2004},
   Month = {September},
   ISBN = {1891853880},
   url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.4324/9781936331468},
   Doi = {10.4324/9781936331468},
   Key = {fds267061}
}

@misc{fds152185,
   Author = {Newell, R.G.},
   Title = {Maximising Value in Multi-species Fisheries},
   Journal = {Ian Axford Fellowship in Public Policy, New Zealand
             Fulbright Program},
   Publisher = {Wellington, New Zealand},
   Year = {2004},
   url = {http://www.nicholas.duke.edu/people/faculty/newell/newellr.pdf},
   Key = {fds152185}
}

@misc{fds152187,
   Author = {Sanchirico, J.N. and R.G. Newell},
   Title = {Catching market Efficiencies},
   Journal = {Resources},
   Volume = {150},
   Series = {Spring},
   Pages = {8-11},
   Year = {2003},
   url = {http://www.nicholas.duke.edu/people/faculty/newell/PublishedResources.pdf},
   Key = {fds152187}
}

@misc{fds267103,
   Author = {Newell, R},
   Title = {Discounting the Benefits of Climate Change Mitigation: How
             Much Do Uncertain Rates Increase Valuations?},
   Pages = {52 pages},
   Publisher = {Pew Center on Blobal Climate Change, Washington,
             DC},
   Year = {2001},
   Month = {December},
   url = {http://hdl.handle.net/10161/7542 Duke open
             access},
   Key = {fds267103}
}

@misc{fds70491,
   Author = {Anderson, S.T. and R.G. Newell},
   Title = {Prospects for Carbon Capture and Storage
             Technologies},
   Journal = {Discussion Paper 02-68, Resources for the
             Future},
   Publisher = {Washington, D.C.},
   url = {http://www.nicholas.duke.edu/people/faculty/newell/Newell_0268.pdf},
   Key = {fds70491}
}


Duke University * Arts & Sciences * Economics * Faculty * Research * Staff * Master's * Ph.D. * Reload * Login