![]() |
Faculty Database Political Science Arts & Sciences Duke University |
|
HOME > Arts & Sciences > Political Science > Faculty | Search Help Login ![]() ![]() |
| Publications of Georg Vanberg :chronological alphabetical by type listing:%% @article{fds358020, Author = {Broman, B and Vanberg, G}, Title = {Feuding, arbitration, and the emergence of an independent judiciary}, Journal = {Constitutional Political Economy}, Volume = {33}, Number = {2}, Pages = {162-199}, Year = {2022}, Month = {June}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10602-021-09341-x}, Abstract = {Anthropologists, historians, and political economists suggest that private violence—feuding—provides order and enforces agreements in the absence of a state. We ground these accounts in a series of formal models that shows the relationship between feuding, informal arbitration, and formal judicial resolution. Feuding enables cooperation by deterring exploitative behavior, but its ability to do so is conditioned by two credible commitment problems that affect both militarily weak and strong actors. These commitment problems can be partially ameliorated through arbitration, even in the absence of coercive authority, by providing information that makes the wronged party’s threat to feud more credible. Transitioning to a formal, coercive justice system, however, represents a qualitative change to the nature of disputing—a change that can be universally beneficial. We therefore provide a new explanation for the creation of independent courts rooted in the logic of dispute resolution and illustrate this explanation with reference to the creation of the Imperial Chamber Court of the Holy Roman Empire.}, Doi = {10.1007/s10602-021-09341-x}, Key = {fds358020} } @article{fds352895, Author = {Martin, LW and Vanberg, G}, Title = {Coalition Government, Legislative Institutions, and Public Policy in Parliamentary Democracies}, Journal = {American Journal of Political Science}, Volume = {64}, Number = {2}, Pages = {325-340}, Year = {2020}, Month = {April}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/ajps.12453}, Abstract = {Most democracies are governed by coalitions, comprising multiple political parties with conflicting policy positions. The prevalence of these governments poses a significant question: Which parties' electoral commitments are ultimately reflected in government policy? Recent theories have challenged our understanding of multiparty government, arguing that the relative influence of coalition parties depends crucially on institutional context. Specifically, where institutions allow credible enforcement of bargains, policy should reflect a compromise among all governing parties; where such institutions are absent, the preferences of parties controlling the relevant ministries should prevail. Critically, empirical work has thus far failed to provide direct evidence for this conditional relationship. Analyzing changes in social protection policies in 15 parliamentary democracies, we provide the first systematic evidence that the strength of legislative institutions significantly shapes the relative policy influence of coalition parties. Our findings have implications for our understanding of coalition government, policymaking, and electoral responsiveness.}, Doi = {10.1111/ajps.12453}, Key = {fds352895} } @article{fds352896, Author = {Martin, LW and Vanberg, G}, Title = {What You See Is Not Always What You Get: Bargaining before an Audience under Multiparty Government}, Journal = {American Political Science Review}, Volume = {114}, Number = {4}, Pages = {1138-1154}, Year = {2020}, Month = {January}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0003055420000337}, Abstract = {Party elites in coalition governments are acutely aware that the deals they strike will be critically evaluated by their supporters, and that they risk losing support if they are perceived as ineffective negotiators. This has a powerful influence on the bargains parties strike. Because most supporters are unaware of the complex aspects of bargains and instead rely on simple heuristics to evaluate their most visible features, parties have incentives to meet supporter expectations primarily on easily observable outcomes. To do so, they make trade-offs on less observable outcomes. This implies that the more visible features of a bargain typically do not accurately reflect the relative success of parties in coalition negotiations. We evaluate our argument using original data on the office rewards and policy risks of portfolio allocation in 16 parliamentary democracies. Our findings support our argument, and they have important implications for the nature of representation under multiparty government.}, Doi = {10.1017/S0003055420000337}, Key = {fds352896} } @article{fds340933, Author = {Fortunato, D and Martin, LW and Vanberg, G}, Title = {Committee Chairs and Legislative Review in Parliamentary Democracies}, Journal = {British Journal of Political Science}, Volume = {49}, Number = {2}, Pages = {785-797}, Year = {2019}, Month = {April}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0007123416000673}, Abstract = {Recent research on parliamentary institutions has demonstrated that legislatures featuring strong committees play an important role in shaping government policy. However, the impact of the legislators who lead these committees - committee chairs - is poorly understood. This study provides the first examination of whether the partisan control of committee chairs in parliamentary systems has a systematic impact on legislative scrutiny. The article argues that committee chairs can, in principle, use their significant agenda powers to serve two purposes: providing opposition parties with a greater ability to scrutinize government policy proposals, and enabling government parties to better police one another. Analyzing the legislative histories of 1,100 government bills in three parliamentary democracies, the study finds that control of committee chairs significantly strengthens the ability of opposition parties to engage in legislative review. The analysis also suggests that government parties' ability to monitor their coalition allies does not depend on control of committee chairs.}, Doi = {10.1017/S0007123416000673}, Key = {fds340933} } @article{fds340472, Author = {Vanberg, G}, Title = {Constitutional political economy, democratic theory and institutional design}, Journal = {Public Choice}, Volume = {177}, Number = {3-4}, Pages = {199-216}, Publisher = {Springer Nature America, Inc}, Year = {2018}, Month = {December}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0570-0}, Abstract = {Democracy and constitutionalism are both central to the Western political tradition. And yet, constitutional restrictions are often perceived to be in tension with democratic commitments. I argue that the constitutional political economy approach developed by Nobel Laureate James Buchanan resolves the tension between constitutionalism and the values of democratic governance by shifting the analysis from a system-attributes perspective that focuses on the particular institutional properties of a political order to a system-legitimacy perspective that focuses on the manner in which political institutions gain democratic legitimacy. In so doing, the approach reveals that constitutionalism can be understood as a natural expression of democratic values.}, Doi = {10.1007/s11127-018-0570-0}, Key = {fds340472} } @misc{fds355649, Author = {Todd, JD and Cho, M and Vanberg, G}, Title = {Politics, Polarization, and the U.S. Supreme Court}, Pages = {41-66}, Booktitle = {The U.S. Supreme Court and Contemporary Constitutional Law: The Obama Era and Its Legacy}, Publisher = {Nomos / Routledge}, Editor = {Kaiser, A-B and Petersen, N and Saurer, J}, Year = {2018}, ISBN = {9780367182311}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.5771/9783845289496-41}, Abstract = {In recent decades, the American political system has become increasingly polarized. Has this trend affected the U.S. Supreme Court? In this chapter, we approach the question empirically through seven decades’ worth of data on the nomination, confirmation, law clerk hires, and voting behaviors of the justices. We find strong evidence of increased polarization in the perceived ideology of nominees and in the Senate’s confirmation process. However, polarization’s impact is less clear-cut where the behavior of the justices themselves is concerned. While new patterns such as ideological homophily in the clerk hiring process and partisan sorting in voting behaviors point toward greater polarization, network analysis of the voting coalitions reveals that moderate levels of polarization are not new to the Court.}, Doi = {10.5771/9783845289496-41}, Key = {fds355649} } @article{fds354338, Author = {Gulati, M and Vanberg, G}, Title = {Financial Crises and Constitutional Compromise}, Year = {2017}, Key = {fds354338} } @article{fds328612, Author = {Munger, M and Vanberg, G}, Title = {Gordon Tullock as a political scientist}, Journal = {Constitutional Political Economy}, Volume = {27}, Number = {2}, Pages = {194-213}, Publisher = {Springer Nature}, Year = {2016}, Month = {April}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10602-016-9214-x}, Abstract = {We consider Gordon Tullock’s impact in political science, focusing on his influence as a scholar and as an academic entrepreneur. It is common to think of Tullock as a “natural economist,” but his formal training at Chicago encompassed considerable coursework related to political science. We consider three sources of information to draw conclusions about Tullock’s contributions in political science: (1) Course syllabi; (2) Citations in academic political science journals; and (3) Impact on the careers of important political scientists, and shaping the intellectual agenda. Our conclusion is that, while Tullock’s work is clearly significant for central questions in political science, and has received some attention, his primary legacy lies in the impact he had on launching and shaping the careers of prominent political scientists, and thus the development of political science scholarship.}, Doi = {10.1007/s10602-016-9214-x}, Key = {fds328612} } @article{fds324046, Author = {Benjamin, S and Vanberg, G}, Title = {Judicial Retirements and the Staying Power of U.S. Supreme Court Decisions}, Journal = {Journal of Empirical Legal Studies}, Volume = {13}, Number = {1}, Pages = {5-26}, Year = {2016}, Key = {fds324046} } @book{fds328613, Author = {Vanberg, G}, Title = {Constitutional courts in comparative perspective: A theoretical assessment}, Volume = {18}, Pages = {167-185}, Publisher = {ANNUAL REVIEWS}, Year = {2015}, Month = {May}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1146/annurev-polisci-040113-161150}, Abstract = {In many democratic polities, constitutional courts significantly shape the political landscape. Yet, how they are able to do so is a puzzle: With limited resources at their disposal, and no direct powers of enforcement, judges must rely on the willingness of executives and legislators to comply with their decisions and to respect judicial authority. This essay surveys recent literature that has explored the conditions that sustain judicial authority. I contrast explanations that highlight the benefits that independent courts can provide to other policy makers ("endogenous explanations") with explanations that emphasize the constraints that keep executives and legislators from undermining the judiciary ("exogenous explanations"). I conclude by exploring the role of strategic judicial behavior in maintaining and expanding judicial power.}, Doi = {10.1146/annurev-polisci-040113-161150}, Key = {fds328613} } @article{fds328615, Author = {Martin, LW and Vanberg, G}, Title = {Parties and policymaking in multiparty governments: The legislative median, ministerial autonomy, and the coalition compromise}, Journal = {American Journal of Political Science}, Volume = {58}, Number = {4}, Pages = {979-996}, Publisher = {WILEY}, Year = {2014}, Month = {October}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/ajps.12099}, Abstract = {In parliamentary democracies, governments are typically composed of multiple political parties working together in a coalition. Such governments must confront a fundamental challenge in policymaking-the preferences of coalition parties often diverge significantly, but the government can adopt only one common policy on any specific issue. This fact raises a critical question that has far-reaching implications for the quality of democratic representation: Whose preferences are ultimately reflected in coalition policy choices? In this study, we explore three competing answers to this question derived from the theoretical literature on multiparty governance and parliamentary institutions. Our findings, based on an analysis of the legislative history of more than 1,000 government bills from three parliamentary democracies, strongly suggest that coalition policies reflect a compromise between government parties rather than the preferences of the ministers proposing them or the preferences of the median party in the legislature.}, Doi = {10.1111/ajps.12099}, Key = {fds328615} } @article{fds328614, Author = {Martin, LW and Vanberg, G}, Title = {A step in the wrong direction: An appraisal of the zero-intelligence model of government formation}, Journal = {Journal of Politics}, Volume = {76}, Number = {4}, Pages = {873-879}, Publisher = {University of Chicago Press}, Year = {2014}, Month = {July}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0022381614000474}, Abstract = {In a recent article in the Journal of Politics, Golder, Golder, and Siegel (2012) argue that models of government formation should be rebuilt "from the ground up." They propose to do so with a "zero-intelligence" model of government formation. They claim that this model makes no theoretical assumptions beyond the requirement that a potential government, to be chosen, must be preferred by all its members and a legislative majority to the incumbent administration. They also claim that, empirically, their model does significantly better than existing models in predicting formation outcomes. We disagree with both claims. Theoretically, their model is unrestrictive in terms of its institutional assumptions, but it imposes a highly implausible behavioral assumption that drives the key results. Empirically, their assessment of the performance of the zero-intelligence model turns on data that are of limited relevance in testing coalition theories. We demonstrate that the predictions of the zero-intelligence model are no more accurate than random guesses, in stark contrast to the predictions of well-established approaches in traditional coalition research. We conclude that scholars would be ill-advised to dismiss traditional approaches in favor of the approach advanced by Golder, Golder, and Siegel.}, Doi = {10.1017/S0022381614000474}, Key = {fds328614} } @article{fds297453, Author = {Fox, J and Vanberg, G}, Title = {Narrow versus broad judicial decisions}, Journal = {Journal of Theoretical Politics}, Volume = {26}, Number = {3}, Pages = {355-383}, Publisher = {SAGE Publications}, Year = {2014}, Month = {July}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/0951629813502709}, Abstract = {A central debate among judges and legal scholars concerns the appropriate scope of judicial opinions: should decisions be narrow, and stick to the facts at hand, or should they be broad, and provide guidance in related contexts? A central argument for judicial ‘minimalism’ holds that judges should rule narrowly because they lack the knowledge required to make general rules to govern unknown future circumstances. In this paper, we challenge this argument. Our argument focuses on the fact that, by shaping the legal landscape, judicial decisions affect the policies that are adopted, and that may therefore subsequently be challenged before the court. Using a simple model, we demonstrate that in such a dynamic setting, in which current decisions shape future cases, judges with limited knowledge confront incentives to rule broadly precisely because they are ignorant.}, Doi = {10.1177/0951629813502709}, Key = {fds297453} } @misc{fds305588, Author = {Vanberg, GS}, Title = {Legislative Institutions and Coalition Government}, Pages = {800 pages}, Booktitle = {The Oxford Handbook of Legislative Studies}, Publisher = {Oxford University Press}, Editor = {Martin, S and Saalfeld, T and Strøm, KW}, Year = {2014}, Month = {June}, ISBN = {0199653011}, Abstract = {The 33 chapters in The Oxford Handbook of Legislative Studies, written by 47 of the most distinguished legislative scholars, provide a comprehensive and up-to-date description and assessment of the state of the art in legislative studies.}, Key = {fds305588} } @article{fds297459, Author = {Martin, LW and Vanberg, G}, Title = {Multiparty government, fiscal institutions, and public spending}, Journal = {Journal of Politics}, Volume = {75}, Number = {4}, Pages = {953-967}, Publisher = {University of Chicago Press}, Year = {2013}, Month = {October}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0022381613000947}, Abstract = {A large body of research has claimed that budget making by multiparty governments constitutes a common pool resource (CPR) problem that leads them to engage in higher levels of spending than single-party governments and, further, that this upwards fiscal pressure increases with the number of parties in the coalition. We offer a significant modification of the conventional wisdom. Drawing on recent developments in the literature on coalition governance, as well as research on fiscal institutions, we argue that budgetary rules can mitigate the CPR logic provided that they (1) reduce the influence of individual parties in the budget process and (2) generate endogenous incentives to resist spending demands by coalition partners. Our empirical evaluation, based on spending patterns in 15 European democracies over nearly 40 years, provides clear support for this contention. Restrictive budgetary procedures can eliminate the expansionary fiscal pressures associated with growing coalition size. Our conclusions suggest that there is room for addressing contemporary concerns over the size of the public sector in multiparty democracies through appropriate reforms to fiscal institutions, and they also have implications for debates about the merits of proportional and majoritarian models of democracy that are, at least in part, characterized by the difference between coalition and single-party governance. © Southern Political Science Association 2013.}, Doi = {10.1017/S0022381613000947}, Key = {fds297459} } @misc{fds297454, Author = {Vanberg, G and Martin, L}, Title = {“Legislative Institutions and Coalition Government.”}, Booktitle = {Oxford Handbook of Legislative Studies}, Publisher = {Oxford Univeristy Press}, Editor = {Saalfeld, T and Strøm, K and Martin, S}, Year = {2013}, ISBN = {0199653011}, Abstract = {The 33 chapters in The Oxford Handbook of Legislative Studies, written by 47 of the most distinguished legislative scholars, provide a comprehensive and up-to-date description and assessment of the state of the art in legislative studies.}, Key = {fds297454} } @misc{fds354339, Author = {Vanberg, G and Martin, L}, Title = {“Legislative Institutions and Coalition Government.”}, Booktitle = {Oxford Handbook of Legislative Studies}, Publisher = {Oxford Univeristy Press}, Editor = {Saalfeld, T and Strøm, K and Martin, S}, Year = {2013}, Key = {fds354339} } @misc{fds297449, Author = {Vanberg, GS}, Title = {John Marshall Has Made His Decision: Implementation, Transparency, and Public Support}, Pages = {320 pages}, Booktitle = {Institutional Games and the U.S. Supreme Court}, Publisher = {University of Virginia Press}, Editor = {Rogers, JR and Flemming, RB and Bond, JR}, Year = {2012}, Month = {October}, ISBN = {0813934192}, Abstract = {Offering new ways of understanding the complexity and consequences of these interactions, the volume joins a growing body of work that considers these influential interactions among various branches of the U.S. government.}, Key = {fds297449} } @misc{fds328616, Author = {Vanberg, G}, Title = {"John Marshall has made his decision": Implementation,transparency, and public support}, Pages = {69-96}, Booktitle = {Institutional Games and the U.S. Supreme Court}, Year = {2012}, Month = {September}, ISBN = {9780813925271}, Key = {fds328616} } @article{fds297458, Author = {Carrubba, C and Friedman, B and Martin, AD and Vanberg, G}, Title = {Who Controls the Content of Supreme Court Opinions?}, Journal = {American Journal of Political Science}, Volume = {56}, Number = {2}, Pages = {400-412}, Publisher = {WILEY}, Year = {2012}, Month = {April}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-5907.2011.00557.x}, Abstract = {Conventional arguments identify either the median justice or the opinion author as the most influential justices in shaping the content of Supreme Court opinions. We develop a model of judicial decision making that suggests that opinions are likely to reflect the views of the median justice in the majority coalition. This result derives from two features of judicial decision making that have received little attention in previous models. The first is that in deciding a case, justices must resolve a concrete dispute, and that they may have preferences over which party wins the specific case confronting them. The second is that justices who are dissatisfied with an opinion are free to write concurrences (and dissents). We demonstrate that both features undermine the bargaining power of the Court's median and shift influence towards the coalition median. An empirical analysis of concurrence behavior provides significant support for the model. © 2011, Midwest Political Science Association.}, Doi = {10.1111/j.1540-5907.2011.00557.x}, Key = {fds297458} } @article{fds297447, Author = {Vanberg, GS and Vanberg, V}, Title = {Towards a (re-)integration of the social sciences: The Calculus of Consent at 50}, Journal = {Public Choice}, Volume = {152}, Pages = {245-252}, Year = {2012}, Key = {fds297447} } @article{fds297457, Author = {Vanberg, G}, Title = {Substance vs. procedure: Constitutional enforcement and constitutional choice}, Journal = {Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization}, Volume = {80}, Number = {2}, Pages = {309-318}, Publisher = {Elsevier BV}, Year = {2011}, Month = {October}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2011.06.030}, Abstract = {The constitutional political economy research program established by Nobel Laureate James M. Buchanan provides a rigorous analytical framework for the analysis of constitutional choice. I focus on two issues that have received only limited attention in the CPE literature: the problem of constitutional enforcement and the role of judicial review. I demonstrate that incorporating a concern for enforcement into constitutional analysis has significant implications for the the choice among rules, and suggests that procedural constitutional constraints have significant advantages over constitutional norms that attempt to secure broader, substantive values. © 2011 Elsevier B.V.}, Doi = {10.1016/j.jebo.2011.06.030}, Key = {fds297457} } @book{fds297460, Author = {Martin, LW and Vanberg, G}, Title = {Parliaments and Coalitions: The Role of Legislative Institutions in Multiparty Governance}, Pages = {1-192}, Publisher = {Oxford University Press}, Year = {2011}, Month = {July}, ISBN = {9780199607884}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199607884.001.0001}, Abstract = {Coalition governments are the norm in most of the world's parliamentary democracies. Because these governments are comprised of multiple political parties, they are subject to tensions that are largely absent under single-party government. The pressures of electoral competition and the necessity of delegating substantial authority to ministers affiliated with specific parties threaten the compromise agreements that are at the heart of coalition governance. The central argument of this book is that strong legislative institutions play a critical role in allowing parties to deal with these tensions and to enforce coalition bargains. Based on an analysis of roughly 1,300 government bills across five democracies (Denmark, France, Germany, Ireland, and the Netherlands), the book paints a detailed picture of the treatment of government legislation in contemporary parliaments. Two central contributions emerge. First, the book forces a reconsideration of the common perception that legislatures are largely irrelevant institutions in European democracies. The data presented here make a compelling case that parliaments that feature strong committee systems play an influential role in shaping policy. Second, the book contributes to the field of coalition governance. While scholars have developed detailed accounts of the birth and death of coalitions, much less is known about the manner in which coalitions govern between these bookend events. This book contributes to a richer understanding of how multiparty governments make policy.}, Doi = {10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199607884.001.0001}, Key = {fds297460} } @article{fds328617, Author = {Engstrom, EJ and Vanberg, G}, Title = {Assessing the Allocation of Pork: Evidence From Congressional Earmarks}, Journal = {American Politics Research}, Volume = {38}, Number = {6}, Pages = {959-985}, Publisher = {SAGE Publications}, Year = {2010}, Month = {October}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/1532673X10369529}, Abstract = {Distributive politics represents one of the most important and controversial aspects of legislative policymaking. In the U.S. Congress, controversies over distributive politics are most evident in the area of legislative earmarking. In this article, we employ a unique set of data matching earmarks to their legislative sponsors to assess the leading explanations of distributive politics. We find that members of the majority party do considerably better than equally situated members of the minority. Moreover, party leaders target earmarks to those holding pivotal agenda-setting positions and to electorally vulnerable members. These findings have direct implications for both the extensive political science literature on distributive politics and the practical politics of earmarking reform. © The Author(s) 2010.}, Doi = {10.1177/1532673X10369529}, Key = {fds328617} } @misc{fds297450, Author = {Vanberg, GS}, Title = {Establishing and Maintaining Judicial Independence}, Pages = {828 pages}, Booktitle = {The Oxford Handbook of Law and Politics}, Publisher = {Oxford University Press}, Editor = {Whittington, KE and Kelemen, RD and Caldeira, GA}, Year = {2010}, Month = {June}, ISBN = {0191615064}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/oxfordhb/9780199208425.003.0007}, Abstract = {This Handbook provides a comprehensive survey of the field of law and politics in all its diversity, ranging from such traditional subjects as theories of jurisprudence, constitutionalism, judicial politics and law-and-society to such re ...}, Doi = {10.1093/oxfordhb/9780199208425.003.0007}, Key = {fds297450} } @article{fds297446, Author = {Vanberg, GS}, Title = {The Will of the People: A Comparative Perspective on Friedman}, Journal = {Michigan State Law Review}, Volume = {3}, Pages = {717-728}, Year = {2010}, ISSN = {1087-5468}, Key = {fds297446} } @article{fds297456, Author = {Vanberg, G and Engstrom, E}, Title = {Assessing the Partisan Allocation of Pork: Evidence from Congressional Earmarks}, Journal = {American Politics Research}, Volume = {38}, Pages = {958-985}, Year = {2010}, Key = {fds297456} } @article{fds297455, Author = {McGuire, KT and Vanberg, G and Smith, CE and Caldeira, GA}, Title = {Measuring policy content on the U.S. Supreme court}, Journal = {Journal of Politics}, Volume = {71}, Number = {4}, Pages = {1305-1321}, Publisher = {University of Chicago Press}, Year = {2009}, Month = {October}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0022381609990107}, Abstract = {Political scientists have developed increasingly sophisticated understandings of the influences on Supreme Court decision making. Yet, much less attention has been paid to empirical measures of the Court's ideological output. We develop a theory of the interactions between rational litigants, lower court judges, and Supreme Court justices. We argue that the most common measure of the Supreme Court's ideological outputwhether the Court's decision is liberal or conservativesuffers from systematic bias. We trace this bias empirically and explain the undesirable consequences it has for empirical analyses of judicial behavior. Specifically, we show that, although the Court's preferences are positively correlated with the ideological direction of the justices decision to reverse a lower court, the attitudes of the justices are negatively relatedand significantly soto the ideological direction of outcomes that affirm lower court decisions. We also offer a solution that allows scholars to work around this affirmance bias. © 2009 Copyright Southern Political Science Association.}, Doi = {10.1017/S0022381609990107}, Key = {fds297455} } @article{fds297442, Author = {Vanberg, GS and Martin, L}, Title = {Reply to Benoit and Laver}, Journal = {Political Analysis}, Volume = {16}, Number = {1}, Pages = {112-114}, Publisher = {Oxford University Press (OUP)}, Year = {2008}, ISSN = {1476-4989}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/pan/mpm018}, Abstract = {<jats:p>We appreciate the positive reception of our transformation by Benoit and Laver (hereafter, BL), and we are grateful that they have incorporated it into the Wordscores package. Because their comment highlights a fundamental difference between the Martin-Vanberg (MV) and Laver-Benoit-Garry (LBG) approaches that is critical to the choice among transformations, we offer some brief comments that will allow users to make an informed decision regarding the appropriate use of the transformations. The central issue concerns comparisons between reference and virgin texts. As BL point out, researchers will often be interested in making such comparisons, and the LBG and MV transformations can yield substantially different results. In light of these differences, BL's primary suggestion is to focus analysis on the raw scores, which can be obtained for reference as well as virgin texts. We wholeheartedly agree with this prescription. In fact, it is precisely a concern for faithfully reporting the raw score information, while making it more intuitive, that motivates the MV transformation. As we show below, the MV transformation accurately reflects all and nothing but the information contained in raw scores. Therefore, “users [who] get eye strain” by looking at raw scores can safely substitute MV scores and be confident that the information provided is equivalent. The same will typically not be true of LBG scores.</jats:p>}, Doi = {10.1093/pan/mpm018}, Key = {fds297442} } @article{fds297443, Author = {Vanberg, GS and Martin, L}, Title = {A Robust Transformation Procedure for Interpreting Political Texts}, Journal = {Political Analysis}, Volume = {16}, Number = {1}, Pages = {93-100}, Publisher = {Cambridge University Press (CUP)}, Year = {2008}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/pan/mpm010}, Abstract = {In a recent article in the American Political Science Review, Laver, Benoit, and Garry (2003, "Extracting policy positions from political texts using words as data," 97:311-331) propose a new method for conducting content analysis. Their Wordscores approach, by automating text-coding procedures, represents an advance in content analysis that will potentially have a large long-term impact on research across the discipline. To allow substantive interpretation, the scores produced by the Wordscores procedure require transformation. In this note, we address several shortcomings in the transformation procedure introduced in the original program. We demonstrate that the original transformation distorts the metric on which content scores are placed - hindering the ability of scholars to make meaningful comparisons across texts - and that it is very sensitive to the texts that are scored - opening up the possibility that researchers may generate, inadvertently or not, results that depend on the texts they choose to include in their analyses. We propose a transformation procedure that solves these problems. © The Author 2007. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of the Society for Political Methodology. All rights reserved.}, Doi = {10.1093/pan/mpm010}, Key = {fds297443} } @article{fds297444, Author = {Vanberg, GS and Martin, L}, Title = {Coalition Government and Political Communication}, Journal = {Political Research Quarterly}, Volume = {61}, Number = {3}, Pages = {502-516}, Publisher = {SAGE Publications}, Year = {2008}, ISSN = {1938-274X}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/1065912907308348}, Abstract = {One of the central challenges facing multiparty governments in parliamentary democracies is the need for coalition parties to communicate to their constituents that they have not strayed significantly from their electoral commitments when agreeing to policy compromises. We argue that one of the main ways parties attempt to make their case to constituents is through their behavior in legislative debate. Debate provides a unique opportunity-tied directly to the policy the government is implementing-to declare party positions on the coalition compromise. In an analysis of several hundred legislative speeches in two parliamentary democracies, we show that coalition parties communicate with constituents much more extensively on internally divisive issues, especially as the next parliamentary elections draw near. We also demonstrate contextual and institutional effects (including the impact of junior ministers) that complement emerging findings in the literature on coalition governance. © 2008 University of Utah.}, Doi = {10.1177/1065912907308348}, Key = {fds297444} } @article{fds297445, Author = {Vanberg, GS and Staton, J}, Title = {The Value of Vagueness: Delegation, Defiance, and Judicial Opinions}, Journal = {American Journal of Political Science}, Volume = {52}, Number = {3}, Pages = {504-519}, Publisher = {WILEY}, Year = {2008}, ISSN = {1540-5907}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-5907.2008.00326.x}, Abstract = {An established line of research demonstrates that vague judicial opinions are less likely to be implemented than clear opinions. Vague opinions thus present a puzzle. Why would judges craft opinions that risk noncompliance? We argue that the relationships between judges and other policy makers in separation-of-powers systems are central to understanding this puzzle. Opinion vagueness can reflect efforts to resolve core tradeoffs associated with judicial policymaking that bear some resemblance to standard accounts of political delegation. Vagueness offers judges the ability to manage their uncertainty over policy outcomes and to hide likely defiance from public view. At the same time, vagueness removes a central source of pressure for compliance that judges can place on other policy makers. Using a game-theoretic model, we identify conditions under which judges use vagueness precisely as legislatures use statutory discretion. We also demonstrate conditions under which judges use vagueness in ways unanticipated by standard delegation accounts. © 2008, Midwest Political Science Association.}, Doi = {10.1111/j.1540-5907.2008.00326.x}, Key = {fds297445} } @article{fds328618, Author = {Rogers, JR and Vanberg, G}, Title = {Resurrecting lochner: A defense of unprincipled judicial activism}, Journal = {Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization}, Volume = {23}, Number = {2}, Pages = {442-468}, Publisher = {Oxford University Press (OUP)}, Year = {2007}, Month = {June}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/jleo/ewm029}, Abstract = {Lochner v. New York, 198 U.S. 45 (1905), stands as one of the Supreme Court's most reviled decisions. We challenge the critical consensus against Lochner and provide a defense, albeit a contingent defense, of "unprincipled" judicial activism. To do so, we develop a game-theoretic model of judicial-legislative interaction. We use the model to compare outcomes generated in a system of legislative supremacy to outcomes generated in a system in which judicial review is provided by a legally unprincipled, activist judiciary. We show that judicial review, even when provided by an activist, politicized judiciary, can promote important constitutional values and improve legislative quality relative to a deferential judiciary. In doing so, we identify an important "passive" component to the effect that judicial review has on legislatures and on legislation. Finally, we demonstrate that the addition of other institutions and constraints on judicial behavior amplify the beneficial effects that judicial review provides to the legislative process.}, Doi = {10.1093/jleo/ewm029}, Key = {fds328618} } @article{fds297441, Author = {Vanberg, GS and Rogers, J}, Title = {Resurrecting Lochner: A Continent Defense of Judicial Activism}, Journal = {Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization}, Pages = {442-468}, Year = {2007}, Key = {fds297441} } @article{fds297440, Author = {Vanberg, GS and Martin, L}, Title = {Coalition Policymaking and Legislative Review}, Journal = {American Political Science Review}, Volume = {99}, Number = {1}, Pages = {93-106}, Publisher = {Cambridge University Press (CUP)}, Year = {2005}, ISSN = {1537-5943}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0003055405051518}, Abstract = {Political scientists know remarkably little about the extent to which legislatures are able to influence policymaking in parliamentary democracies. In this article, we focus on the influence of legislative institutions in periods of coalition government. We show that multiparty governments are plagued by "agency" problems created by delegation to cabinet ministers that increase in severity on issues that divide the coalition. We also argue that the process of legislative review presents an important-but understudied- institutional opportunity for coalition partners to overcome these tensions. We evaluate our argument using original legislative data on over 300 government bills collected from two parliamentary democracies. The central implication of our findings is that legislatures play a more important role in parliamentary democracies than is usually appreciated by providing a key institutional mechanism that allows coalition partners with divergent preferences to govern successfully.}, Doi = {10.1017/S0003055405051518}, Key = {fds297440} } @misc{fds297448, Author = {Vanberg, GS}, Title = {Verfassungsgerichtsbarkeit und Gesetzgebung: Zum politischen Spielraum des Bun-desverfassungsgerichtes}, Booktitle = {Neue theoretische Perspektiven auf das deutsche Regierungssystem}, Publisher = {Max-Planck-Institut f ̈ ur Gesellschafts- forschung}, Editor = {Manow, P and Ganghof, S}, Year = {2005}, Key = {fds297448} } @book{fds297452, Author = {Vanberg, GS}, Title = {The Politics of Constitutional Review in Germany}, Pages = {1-193}, Publisher = {Cambridge University Press}, Year = {2005}, ISBN = {0521836476}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511510427}, Abstract = {Constitutional courts have emerged as central institutions in many advanced democracies. This book investigates the sources and the limits of judicial authority, focusing on the central role of public support for judicial independence. The empirical sections of the book illustrate the theoretical argument in an in-depth study of the German Federal Constitutional Court, including statistical analysis of judicial decisions, case studies, and interviews with judges and legislators. The book's major finding is that the interests of governing majorities, prevailing public opinion, and the transparency of the political environment exert a powerful influence on judicial decisions. Judges are influenced not only by jurisprudential considerations and their policy preferences, but also by strategic concerns. By highlighting this dimension of constitutional review, the book challenges the contention that high court justices are largely unconstrained actors as well as the notion that constitutional courts lack democratic legitimacy.}, Doi = {10.1017/CBO9780511510427}, Key = {fds297452} } @article{fds297439, Author = {Vanberg, GS}, Title = {Policing the Bargain: Coalition Government and Parliamentary Scrutiny}, Journal = {American Journal of Political Science}, Volume = {48}, Number = {1}, Pages = {13-27}, Publisher = {WILEY}, Year = {2004}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.0092-5853.2004.00053.x}, Abstract = {Policymaking by coalition governments creates a classic principal-agent problem. Coalitions are comprised of parties with divergent preferences who are forced to delegate important policymaking powers to individual cabinet ministers, thus raising the possibility that ministers will attempt to pursue policies favored by their own party at the expense of their coalition partners. What is going to keep ministers from attempting to move policy in directions they favor rather than sticking to the "coalition deal"? We argue that parties will make use of parliamentary scrutiny of "hostile" ministerial proposals to overcome the potential problems of delegation and enforce the coalition bargain. Statistical analysis of original data on government bills in Germany and the Netherlands supports this argument. Our findings suggest that parliaments play a central role in allowing multiparty governments to solve intracoalition conflicts.}, Doi = {10.1111/j.0092-5853.2004.00053.x}, Key = {fds297439} } @article{fds305587, Author = {Vanberg, GS}, Title = {Wasting Time? The Impact of Ideology and Size on Delay in Coalition Formation}, Volume = {33}, Number = {2}, Pages = {323-332}, Publisher = {Cambridge University Press (CUP)}, Year = {2003}, Month = {January}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0007123403000140}, Doi = {10.1017/S0007123403000140}, Key = {fds305587} } @article{fds305586, Author = {Vanberg, GS and Rogers, J}, Title = {Judicial Advisory Opinions and Legislative Outcomes in Comparative Perspective}, Journal = {American Journal of Political Science}, Volume = {46}, Number = {2}, Pages = {379-397}, Publisher = {WILEY}, Year = {2002}, Month = {January}, ISSN = {1540-5907}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/3088383}, Abstract = {High courts in eleven U.S. states (and a number of countries) provide advisory opinions on pending legislation when requested by the executive or legislative branch of the government. To examine the implications of the advisory mechanism for institutional behavior and for policy outcomes, we develop and compare results form two incomplete-information models of judicial-legislative interaction. One game models judicial-legislative interaction with "ordinary" judicial review, the other models the interaction with an advisory option. We show how the advisory mechanism alters policy outcomes relative to outcomes that would be realized without the advisory option. We then identify the conditions under which legislatures request advisory opinions and when they choose to legislate without them. Finally, we consider whether the advisory mechanism is a welfare-enhancing or welfare-diminishing institution, and identify conditions that explain why some courts are willing to offer advisory opinions while others refuse to do so.}, Doi = {10.2307/3088383}, Key = {fds305586} } @article{fds328619, Author = {Alter, KJ and Dehousse, R and Vanberg, G}, Title = {Law, Political Science and EU Legal Studies: An Interdisciplinary Project?}, Journal = {European Union Politics}, Volume = {3}, Number = {1}, Pages = {113-136}, Publisher = {SAGE Publications}, Year = {2002}, Month = {January}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/1465116502003001006}, Doi = {10.1177/1465116502003001006}, Key = {fds328619} } @article{fds297438, Author = {Vanberg, GS}, Title = {Law, Politics, and Interdisciplinary Work}, Journal = {European Union Politics}, Pages = {127-135}, Year = {2002}, ISSN = {1465-1165}, Key = {fds297438} } @article{fds297437, Author = {Vanberg, GS}, Title = {Legislative-Judicial Relations: A Game-Theoretic Approach to Constitutional Review}, Volume = {45}, Number = {2}, Pages = {346-361}, Publisher = {JSTOR}, Year = {2001}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2669345}, Abstract = {This article develops an imperfect information model of the interactions between legislatures and constitutional courts. The model addresses legislative anticipation of judicial review, legislative reactions to judicial rulings, and the impact of anticipation of such reactions on judicial behavior. The most important finding is that the nature of legislative-judicial relations depends crucially on the political environment in which court and legislature must act, as well as on judicial preferences. Several results are tested in a logit analysis of decisions by the German Constitutional Court from 1983 to 1995.}, Doi = {10.2307/2669345}, Key = {fds297437} } @article{fds328621, Author = {Vanberg, G}, Title = {Establishing judicial independence in West Germany: The impact of opinion leadership and the separation of powers}, Journal = {Comparative Politics}, Volume = {32}, Number = {3}, Pages = {333-353}, Publisher = {JSTOR}, Year = {2000}, Month = {January}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/422370}, Doi = {10.2307/422370}, Key = {fds328621} } @article{fds328620, Author = {Powell, GB and Vanberg, GS}, Title = {Election laws, disproportionality and median correspondence: Implications for two visions of democracy}, Journal = {British Journal of Political Science}, Volume = {30}, Number = {3}, Pages = {383-411}, Publisher = {Cambridge University Press (CUP)}, Year = {2000}, Month = {January}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/s0007123400000168}, Abstract = {Comparative studies of election rules and legislative representation have focused intensively on vote-seat disproportionality as an indication of poor representation. Beginning with citizens' preferences, rather than votes, has important advantages and is especially more appropriate for a majoritarian vision of democracy. We analyse the effect of election rules on both vote-seat correspondence and median left-right correspondence in seventy elections in seventeen countries. We show theoretically the stringent conditions necessary to reduce vote-seat disproportionality in high threshold systems and empirically their high variance (and higher levels) of distortion. Although good median correspondence could be created, in theory, under a wide range of electoral systems, our empirical results suggest that proportional representation (PR) systems tend to outperform single-member district (SMD) systems by this criterion also.}, Doi = {10.1017/s0007123400000168}, Key = {fds328620} } @article{fds328622, Author = {Vanberg, G}, Title = {Intergovernmental fiscal relations}, Journal = {Constitutional Political Economy}, Volume = {10}, Number = {2}, Pages = {199-201}, Year = {1999}, Month = {January}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1023/a:1017272930043}, Doi = {10.1023/a:1017272930043}, Key = {fds328622} } @article{fds328623, Author = {Vanberg, G}, Title = {Abstract judicial review, legislative bargaining, and policy compromise}, Journal = {Journal of Theoretical Politics}, Volume = {10}, Number = {3}, Pages = {299-326}, Publisher = {SAGE Publications}, Year = {1998}, Month = {January}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/0951692898010003005}, Abstract = {The constitutions of many parliamentary democracies provide for abstract judicial review, a proceeding that allows a specified parliamentary minority to initiate judicial review against legislation in the absence of a concrete case. The paper analyzes the impact that this proceeding has on legislative bargaining, using a simple game-theoretic model. The main conclusion is that the most important effects of abstract review are indirect and anticipatory. Furthermore, abstract review results in more moderate legislative proposals than would be expected in its absence. In this sense, it promotes what Lijphart has called 'consensus democracy'. Finally, the model reveals that such moderation depends on the degree of judicial deference towards the legislature. Surprisingly, a court that is not deferential will be appealed to less than a deferential court, even though its influence on policy is larger.}, Doi = {10.1177/0951692898010003005}, Key = {fds328623} } @article{fds328624, Author = {Vanberg, G}, Title = {Reply to Stone Sweet}, Journal = {Journal of Theoretical Politics}, Volume = {10}, Number = {3}, Pages = {339-346}, Publisher = {SAGE Publications}, Year = {1998}, Month = {January}, url = {http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/0951692898010003007}, Doi = {10.1177/0951692898010003007}, Key = {fds328624} } | |
Duke University * Arts & Sciences * Political Science * Faculty * Staff * Grad * Master * Foreign Exchange * Reload * Login |